Reading, Writing, and Religion:
Explaining Hindu and Muslim Literacy Differences in Colonial India
Latika Chaudhary Jared Rubin
Economics Fellow Assistant Professor
Stanford University California State University, Fullerton
First Draft: March 20, 2009
Preliminary: Please do not cite without authors’ permission.
Abstract
In this paper, we analyze the factors underlying differences in Hindu and Muslim
literacy rates in colonial India. Using a novel data set, we find the striking result
that Muslim literacy is strongly and negatively correlated with the proportion of
Muslims in the district. We then econometrically test three potential hypotheses to
account for this result: the presence of lower returns to education for Muslims in
Muslim-dominant districts; colonial education policies interacting with local
preferences to stifle the development of primary schools; a “legacy of
dependence” between religious and political authorities in districts formerly ruled
by Muslim emperors, entailing significant power for Muslim scholars, many of
whom encouraged Qur’an memorization rather than literacy.
1
INTRODUCTION
Human capital is often linked with higher income per-capita, greater worker productivity,
higher life expectancy, and other factors positively associated with economic growth and
development (see Schultz 1983, Dreze and Sen 1998 among others). Despite the social and
private benefits of education, several countries, religions, and social groups have experienced
significant hurdles in trying to increase their level of schooling.
1
In this paper, we analyze
historical differences in educational attainment between Hindus and Muslims in British India and
explore a variety of socio-economic explanations to account for the differential patterns of
human capital accumulation observed across the two groups.
Although the economic and educational differences between Brahmans (the traditional
elite caste of Hindus) and socially marginalized groups (such as the lower castes and tribes) have
received some attention in the literature (Ghurye 1961; Srinivas 1998), we know little about the
factors underlying the differences between Hindus and Muslims. We address this limitation by
constructing a new historical dataset that merges information on Hindu and Muslim specific
literacy rates with various economic and social characteristics of Indian districts in the major
provinces of British India in the early 20
th
century.
Average Muslim literacy was below average Hindu literacy in this period (in 1911, the
male Hindu literacy rate was 13.1% and the male Muslim literacy rate was 6.8%), but there was
tremendous heterogeneity between provinces. For example, in Bengal 20.3% of Hindu males
were able to read and write in any language as compared to only 7.7% of Muslim males.
However, in other provinces such as Madras and the United Provinces, Muslims enjoyed
comparable or even slightly higher literacy than Hindus. Female literacy was very low for both
1
Fernandez and Rodrick (1991), Galor and Moav (2006), and Rajan (2009), among many others, focus on the role
of policy.
2
religious groups, but the provincial patterns are very similar to those for males. These statistics
suggest that the Muslim experience was not uniform within British India, and that perhaps local
conditions interacted with historical and institutional factors, leading to marked differences in the
patterns of human capital development across the two religious groups in different parts of the
sub-continent.
At an individual level, the choice to invest in becoming literate involves a cost-benefit
calculation whereby individual characteristics – namely ability, religious affiliation, and parental
income and education – interact with community or district characteristics such as the level of
local development and public spending on education. Outcomes at the district level are thus an
aggregate measure of the underlying individual decisions, assuming that the probability that an
individual who invests in education or literacy becomes literate is the same across groups,
holding all else constant. With this simple education production function in mind, we
econometrically explore the effects of different socio-economic variables on Hindu and Muslim
literacy rates.
The preliminary findings suggest that both religions were responsive to demand side
conditions such as the level of development and local occupational structure. However, Muslim
literacy is negatively associated with the presence of other Muslims in the district, while there is
little evidence of a similar relationship relating Hindu literacy to the presence of other Hindus in
the area. The proportion of Muslims has a large and statistically significant correlation with
overall Muslim literacy, gender-specific Muslim literacy, and age cohort-specific Muslim
literacy. Moreover, this negative effect of the share of Muslims on Muslim literacy persists even
after we control for unobservable differences across Indian provinces by including province
fixed effects. We also find that Hindu literacy is positively associated with the presence of
3
Muslims in the district, which suggests a possible crowding out of Muslims (from the
educational system), a crowding in of Hindus, or some combination of the two.
Our baseline regressions (without any economic and social controls) reveal that a 10
percentage point increase in the share of Muslims leads to a 1.2 to 1.8 percentage point decrease
in the Muslim literacy rate and a 0.8 to 1.3 percentage increase in Hindu literacy, ceteris paribus.
A variety of explanations can account for these interesting and important results.
2
First, it could
simply be the case that returns to education for Muslims in Muslim dominant districts were
lower in the colonial period as compared to the returns for Muslims in districts with a smaller
population of Muslims. To address this issue, we add a variety of controls associated with
district-level development that also may be correlated with literacy, such as urban population
share, and the district occupational structure. Adding these controls weakens, but does not
eliminate, the negative effect of the presence of Muslims on Muslim literacy, although it greatly
weakens the positive association between the presence of Muslims and Hindu literacy.
Second, we test whether colonial educational policies interacted with local preferences to
either ameliorate or exacerbate private demand for education. In order to improve outcomes
among groups with below average literacy, the Imperial Government often set up model schools
in districts with a larger proportion of Muslims, lower castes, and tribal groups. However,
Chaudhary (2009a) shows that this policy was not particularly effective at increasing literacy
among these groups. Primary schools were correlated with subsequent literacy, but colonial
policy often focused on providing secondary schools that did not translate into substantial
2
Our results bear a striking resemblance to other studies that have found similar negative effects on the educational
attainment of minority groups living in areas heavily populated by their own group such as blacks in the United
States (Margo 1990; Hanushek, Kaln, and Rivkin 2004). While the explanations for some of these findings in US
studies are related to differences in the supply of schooling, it could also be related to differential preferences within
minority groups living in non-minority versus minority areas (Fryer and Austen-Smith 2005). We concentrate
primarily on the former type of explanation in this paper.
4
increases in overall literacy. While a small number of educated Muslims may have benefited
from these secondary schools, these policies may have hurt the development of Muslim literacy
by not providing a larger number of primary schools. To address the effects of colonial policies,
we include public spending on rural primary education as an additional control and also study the
relationship between public schools and fraction Muslim. Our results are robust to the inclusion
of public educational expenditures and as expected we find that districts with a larger share of
Muslims also had more public schools. Hence, colonial policies cannot account for the negative
Muslim effect.
Third and finally, there could be an omitted or unobservable factor driving these patterns
on Muslim literacy. Any variable that differentially affects Muslim literacy in Muslim-dominant
districts versus other districts can account for the negative result on the proportion of Muslims
and Muslim literacy. For example, previous scholarship on Islam, from Max Weber to Bernard
Lewis, suggests that attributes of Islamic culture – its “conservative” or “mystical” nature – may
explain our finding by differentially affecting incentives to obtain education and literacy. Though
we cannot disprove such hypotheses econometrically, we show that a more nuanced, historically
motivated approach may help explain literacy differences.
Specifically, we argue that where Muslim political authorities ruled in India over long
periods of time, especially during the Mughal reign (1526-1858), there was a strong relationship
between political and religious (Muslim) authority that was an exogenous remnant of the birth of
Islam and the type of institutions that it encouraged (for more, see Rubin 2009). When the
Mughal Empire declined in the eighteenth century, the religious authorities entered the power
vacuum and propagated their own agenda. One way it may have done this was by establishing
5
important institutions (Qur'an reading schools and madrasahs) that encouraged the memorization
of the Qur'an, but may not have necessarily encouraged literacy.
This history suggests that the share of Muslims in a district may merely proxy for the
historical situation in which certain Muslim-dominant regions established institutions that may
have discouraged literacy. If this is true, then areas with weak Islamic political influence should
be less affected by Muslim schools and thus the fraction of Muslims should not contribute to
lower literacy in these districts. We test this hypothesis by controlling for the number of years
that the district was under Muslim rule. Though this is admittedly a noisy proxy, we find that this
variable has a negative and statistically significant effect on Muslim literacy and a positive and
(mostly) statistically significant effect on Hindu literacy. The presence of other Muslims still has
a negative and statistically significant effect on Muslim literacy, but the magnitude of the
coefficient is smaller. A more nuanced approach that incorporates the effects of institutions on
actions and outcomes may thus provide a more complete picture of the relationship between
Hindu-Muslim literacy in this period, which has important implications for the differential
economic development of these two groups within India over the 20
th
century.
HISTORICAL BACKGROUND: EDUCATION, COLONIZATION, AND LITERACY
Beginning in the mid-19
th
century, the former indigenous system of Indian schooling was
largely replaced by a new state system of schooling introduced by the East India Company and
developed further by the colonial government after the East India Company’s rule came to an
end in 1857. Schools were of two types under the former indigenous system: elite religious
schools for students interested in a lifetime of higher education and local elementary schools
where village boys were taught the 3 R’s in the vernacular medium. The religious schools were
6
differentiated by religion (Hindu or Muslim) with upper caste Brahman teachers and pupils
dominating the Hindu (i.e. Sanskrit) religious schools, although Hindus did occasionally teach at
some of the Muslim schools (madrasahs). The local schools also encompassed Qur’an schools
(i.e. maktabs) where Muslim boys learned to read the Qur’an. Some historians suggest that 8 to
12 percent of the male population was literate, but we interpret these estimates with caution, as a
systematic enumeration of literacy did not begin until the early 20
th
century.
3
Under the British system of education, publicly financed and managed schools
(government and local board schools) functioned alongside privately managed aided and unaided
schools. Private aided schools received public subsidies despite being privately managed, while
private unaided schools did not receive any public money. Privately managed schools came
under the authority of the state school system, as they conformed to official education standards
and their students were allowed to take public examinations. Although many of the former
indigenous schools disappeared over this period, some were successfully converted into public
aided schools and the rest were classified as private unrecognized schools.
4
The emphasis on both public and private schools is also reflected in the composition of
educational spending in this period. Public sources of revenues represented 50 percent of total
spending on education, increasing to 60 percent by the 1940s, while fees and private
contributions accounted for the remaining 50 percent. Differences in land revenues were
primarily responsible for differences in public revenues both across and within provinces.
Districts had limited fiscal independence to set tax rates and they received a fraction of their land
revenues to finance public investments on schools and local infrastructure. Although the tax rates
3
See Nurullah and Naik (1951) and Basu (1982) for details. Basu (1982) suggests that literacy was more
commonplace among Brahmans and other upper caste males. Unfortunately, there is no systematic data available to
gauge the spread of schooling or estimate the degree of literacy in the population.
4
See Progress of Education, Quinquennial Reviews (volumes 1897-1927). See Nurullah and Naik (1951), Basu
(1974) and Ghosh (2000) for a historical examination of colonial Indian education.
7
were fixed for districts within the same province, they did vary across provinces. In general, the
eastern provinces of Bengal and Bihar had lower public spending compared to the other
provinces since they received lower land revenues due to the Permanent Settlement of 1793 that
fixed land revenues in cash for perpetuity (Chaudhary 2009b).
As the new state system of education developed over the colonial period, there was a
dramatic increase in spending, number of schools per-capita, and enrollment rates (Chaudhary
2009b). Per-capita spending increased nine-fold between 1881 and 1931 from 95 to 1000 rupees
per 1000 persons and enrollment rates increased to 30 percent of the school age population by
1931. However, literacy patterns did not mirror these gains and less than 10 percent of the
population of British India could read and write as late as 1931.
5
However, the averages for British India mask the substantial heterogeneity across regions
and across religions. Amongst Hindus, literacy patterns generally followed the social hierarchy
of the caste system with Brahmans (the traditional upper castes) enjoying above average literacy
compared to the lower castes. There were also significant differences in enrollment rates and
literacy between Hindus more generally and Muslims, however, with Muslim literacy rates being
lower on average than Hindu literacy rates. Moreover, Hindu-Muslim enrollment differentials
were particularly large at the secondary and post-secondary level. Official reports often point to
religion and poverty to account for the relative educational backwardness of Muslims in the
colonial period. For example, the Fifth Quinquennial review (p. 282) states,
the backwardness [of Muslims] is attributable partly to poverty, partly to
indifference, and partly to their educational wants not being the same as those of
the remainder of the population amongst whom they live. They require their
children to learn the Koran by rote at an age when other children are beginning to
make progress in secular education, and they have a preference for the use of
5
To account for this discrepancy between enrollment and literacy, British officials frequently noted the general
wastage and inefficiency of the Indian education system. See Progress of Education, Tenth Quinquennial Review
(1927-32).
8
Urdu as a medium of instruction, even when it is not the vernacular language of
the locality. Both these causes operate to make the common schools less attractive
to Muhammadans than to members of other creeds and also to make it more
difficult for Government to provide schools suited to their special needs.
Colonial policies tried to bridge the gap between the two religions by offering
scholarships to Muslim students and public subsidies to indigenous Muslim religious schools that
were willing to introduce secular education. However, they often faced heavy resistance from
local Muslim communities that did not view the new state schools in the same positive light as
Hindus. Although colonial efforts were partially successful in raising Muslim primary school
enrollment, Hindu-Muslim differences in both secondary school enrollment and literacy
persisted till the end of colonial rule.
Why did these differences in enrollment and literacy exist and continue to persist over the
colonial period? Were the British correct in attributing the differences to the relative poverty of
Muslims as well as a difference in “educational wants”? Numerous factors may have caused
these differences. In the following sections we attempt to isolate these factors, employing a
unique data set of Hindu and Muslim literacy rates in the early twentieth century as well as
various socio-economic indicators in order to shed light on the causes underlying differences in
Hindu and Muslim literacy rates.
DATA DESCRIPTION
For the empirical analysis, we assemble a new dataset that merges information from the
Indian censuses of 1911 and 1921 to data reported in the Indian District Gazetteers. The dataset
covers all districts in the provinces of Assam, Bengal, Bihar and Orissa, Bombay, Central
9
Province and Berar, Madras, Punjab and United Provinces.
6
These provinces jointly account for
more than 95 percent of the population of British India. We extract data on the social,
educational, occupational, and developmental structure of each district from the colonial
censuses and rely on the Indian district gazetteers for the number of schools, pupils, income and
land tax revenues, and public spending on rural primary education.
Although literacy was enumerated in the earlier censuses, we begin the analysis in 1911
because the definition and enumeration of literates in previous censuses was inconsistent across
provinces. Beginning in 1911, a uniform definition of literacy was adopted whereby an
individual that could both read and write in any language was enumerated as literate. Official
discussions suggest that the definition was clearly understood by the enumerators and the literacy
data are considered reasonably accurate.
7
However, the censuses do note that Muslims were
occasionally frustrated by this definition because even though they could read certain passages
from the Qur’an, the enumerators recorded them as illiterate because they could not write.
8
We
focus on measures of total, gender-specific, and cohort-specific (for the population aged 10 to
20) literacy in 1911 and 1921 disaggregated for Hindus and Muslims.
The age-specific measures of literacy may also raise concerns of measurement error
because individuals often did not know their age. Since numeracy and literacy generally go hand
6
The analysis excludes the pure urban cities of Bombay, Calcutta and Madras because they were so different
socially and economically from the largely rural districts of British India. We also exclude the remote North
Western Frontier Province, Baluchistan, and Burma.
7
In the pre-1911 censuses no specific guidelines were given to enumerators to test for literacy, which led to
substantial variation in the methods adopted across provinces. Although officials point to certain problems with the
post-1911 enumeration such as enumerators on occasion adopting school standards, they do indicate, “the simple
criterion laid down was easily understood and sensibly interpreted” (Census of India 1921, Volume I – Report,
Chapter VIII).
8
Although this may lead to measurement error in the Muslim literacy rate data, there is no reason to believe that this
error would differ in high-Muslim versus low-Muslim districts. If anything, measurement error of this type should
make it more difficult to find a negative effect of Muslims on Muslim literacy because districts with more Muslims
were more likely to have Muslim census enumerators that may have been sympathetic to this argument.
10
in hand, this is to be expected for a country like India in the early 20
th
century.
9
Census
discussions suggest that uncertainty about age was the primary reason for the inaccuracy, so the
measurement error in the cohort specific measure should be classical in nature that still yields
consistent OLS estimates.
In addition to literacy, we used the 1911 and 1921 censuses to construct measures of
development such as urban population share, population density, and the district occupational
structure. Scholars have suggested that some of the smaller occupational categories may be
inaccurate, hence we focus on broader categories: the share of the population supported by
agriculture, commerce, industry, and professionals. We also extracted information on the
population share of important caste and religious groups: Muslims, Christians, and tribes.
Moreover, we also constructed a measure of caste and religious fragmentation to capture the
level of diversity that has been linked to an under-provision of public goods in a variety of
contexts including British India.
10
From the district gazetteers, we extracted data on public educational spending by rural
district boards and income tax revenues.
11
Income taxes and district board expenditures were
missing for several districts in the 1921 cross-section. We used the 1911 income taxes for the
1921 cross-section in provinces where this data was missing since the variation within provinces
is similar although the levels may have increased between 1911 and 1921.
12
Income taxes are a
crude proxy of district income and should be interpreted with caution because these taxes were
9
Numeracy was a common statistical problem with the 19
th
century European censuses as well.
10
See Chaudhary (2009a).
11
Rural districts boards were constituted in the early 1880’s and managed the provision of local public goods such
as infrastructure, education, and medical services at the district level.
12
Likewise, we only use 1911 district board expenditures in the analysis, because public spending changed in this
decade due to the Montague Chelmsford reforms, which ushered in the period of Dyarchy under which British
administrators worked alongside elected Indian ministers in provincial legislatures. See Kumar (1982) for an
overview of the colonial fiscal system.
11
levied on a very small share of individuals in the formal sector of the economy. Nonetheless, this
is the best available local measure of historical income.
Table 1 reports the summary statistics of the main variables. Hindu and Muslim literacy
rates as well as the population share of each religion are shown separately by province in the top
half of the table, while the different socio-economic variables are shown by year in the bottom
half. Overall literacy was very low in British India both among Hindus and Muslims averaging
around 7 percent across districts and religions. The average masks the substantial regional
variations with Muslim literacy ranging from as high as 12 percent in the southern province of
Madras to as low as 2.6 percent in the northern province of Punjab. Some of this variation is
related to the Muslim population share. For example, Muslims enjoy above average literacy in
provinces where they form a smaller share of the population such as Madras and Central
Provinces (4.2 and 6.7 percent respectively) versus provinces such as Bengal and Punjab where
they comprise almost fifty percent of the population. We explore this relationship between
Hindu-Muslim literacy and their respective population shares in more detail in the next section.
13
[INSERT TABLE 1 HERE]
LITERACY RATES AND RELIGIOUS POPULATION
The summary statistics shown in Table 1 suggest that the Muslim population share may
influence Hindu and Muslim literacy rates in British India. To examine this relationship, we run
a baseline regression relating the share of the Hindu and Muslim population to Hindu and
Muslim literacy in 1911 and 1921. Table 2A reports the findings for 1911 in the top panel and
13
Similar to literacy, other socio-economic indicators such as urbanization and the share of the commercial
population are relatively stagnant between 1911 and 1921. Moreover, the low levels of urbanization and
commercialization highlight the remarkable dominance of agriculture in the early 20
th
century Indian economy
(agriculture is the omitted occupational group in the table).
12
for 1921 in the bottom panel. It is evident that the Muslim population is strongly correlated with
the educational performance of both Hindus and Muslims. Columns 1 and 2 suggest that a larger
proportion of Muslims has a positive and statistically significant impact on Hindu literacy but a
negative impact on Muslim literacy in both the 1911 and 1921 cross-sections. A 10 percentage
point increase in fraction Muslim is associated with a 1 percentage point increase in 1911 Hindu
literacy and a 1.4 percentage point decrease in 1911 Muslim literacy. We test for potential non-
linearities in the relationship between literacy and religious population share in columns 3 and 4
by including the square of fraction Hindu and Muslim. The coefficients on the squared terms
suggest that the relationship between Muslim literacy and fraction Muslims is highly non-linear
with more Muslims contributing to lower Muslim literacy at decreasing rate. The relationship
between fraction Muslim and Hindu literacy is not robust to including the squared terms in the
1911 panel, but it remains robust in the 1921 panel.
[INSERT TABLE 2A HERE]
To test whether positive regional selection alone is driving the results on Fraction
Muslim, columns five to eight control for province fixed effects and focus on the within province
variation. The correlation between fraction Muslim and both Hindu and Muslim literacy remains
negative and statistically significant at the 1 percent level for both the 1911 and 1921 cross-
sections although the result for Hindu literacy is insignificant f or the 1911 cross-section.
Fraction Muslim thus appears to be a significant determinant of Muslim literacy in the colonial
period. Muslims were more likely to be literate in districts where they comprised a smaller share
of the population.
Tables 2B and 2C report similar patterns on age and gender-specific literacy rates. As
seen in table 2B, fraction Muslim is negatively correlated with Muslim literacy rates in the
13
population aged 10 to 20 although the magnitude of the effect is slightly larger for total literacy.
Moreover, fraction Muslim also negatively affects both Muslim male and female literacy rates
(table 2C). The results are remarkably robust across the two cross-sections and across
specifications that include province dummies. Why does fraction Muslim have a negative effect
on Muslim literacy? We do not observe any such negative impact of fraction Hindus on Hindu
literacy. Is fraction Muslim a proxy for differential returns to literacy in Muslim dominant
districts or is colonial policy interacting with fraction Muslim to produce this correlation? In the
next section, we dig deeper into this result.
[INSERT TABLES 2B AND 2C HERE]
WHY DOES THE PRESENCE OF MUSLIMS AFFECT LITERACY?
At an individual level, the decision to invest in literacy involves a simple cost and benefit
calculation. If the benefits or returns to literacy (higher wages, social status, and so forth) exceed
the costs (opportunity cost of time, school fees, and the like), then an individual will invest in
literacy. This decision making process is a function of individual characteristics such as ability,
family background, parental education, and social and religious affiliation as well as community
or district characteristics such as economic conditions and public educational investments.
Literacy rates at the district-level are thus a function of the aggregate costs and benefits of
literacy.
Given this framework, one obvious explanation of our finding on Muslim literacy is that
fraction Muslim is capturing some aspect of lower returns to Muslim literacy. For example, if
Muslims lived in less developed or poorer districts, then fraction Muslim may just be capturing
the negative effects of poverty on education. Colonial discussions often note the poor economic
14
status of Muslims in certain parts of the subcontinent such as Bengal where they were more
likely to be poor agricultural laborers (Census of India 1911). To test whether fraction Muslim is
just a proxy for lower returns to Muslim literacy, we include a variety of variables to capture
differences in the costs and benefits of literacy.
First, parental education is a critical input into the schooling decision, so we control for
the population share supported by professionals (doctors, lawyers, and so forth) in a district.
This is perhaps a lower bound on the effect of family education since it limits the educated
parental population to the set of professionals, but it is the best available measure given data
constraints. We also introduce variables to capture the share of the population supported by
commerce and industry because economic structure can also affect schooling. For example, the
opportunity cost of time for a rural child who worked in the field was likely higher than for other
children.
14
Because of the high degree of social heterogeneity in India, we also include a measure of
caste and religious fragmentation that has a strong negative effect on the supply of private
primary schools in the colonial period (Chaudhary 2009a) and could potentially affect the
demand for education in Muslim majority districts. In addition, we control for other religious
minorities, namely tribal groups and Christians. To control for differences in income and
development, we include income tax revenues per-capita, the urbanization rate, and a dummy for
coastal districts. In the absence of more detailed data, these three measures jointly are a good
proxy for average income in the district.
Tables 3A, 3B, and 3C report the findings on Hindu and Muslim literacy controlling for
the social and development variables described above. The literacy outcomes in these tables are
the same as in tables 2A, 2B, and 2C. Although the coefficients on fraction Muslim are
14
The population share supported by agriculture is the omitted category in all the regressions.
15
somewhat smaller in table 3A as compared to table 2A, they still have a negative and statistically
significant impact on Muslim literacy.
15
A 10 percent increase in fraction Muslim translates into
a 0.8 percentage point decrease in 1911 Muslim literacy without province fixed effects (column
2) and a 1.4 percentage point decrease controlling for province dummies (column 6). Our socio-
economic controls thus cut down almost 40 percent of the fraction Muslim effect in the inter-
province specifications (no province FE), but the difference in coefficients is not as striking for
the within province comparisons. The results are again robust to different cross-sections (1911 or
1921), to province fixed effects, and to alternate literacy measures namely literacy in the
population aged 10 to 20 (table 3B) and gender-specific literacy (table 3C).
[INSERT TABLES 3A, 3B AND 3C HERE]
Despite our vast set of controls, we cannot rule out that fraction Muslim is capturing
some dimension of unobservable heterogeneity related to lower returns. For example, our
occupational measures only control for overall commercial and professional population of the
districts and not the Muslim-specific commercial or professional occupation. Clearly, the
Muslim specific occupational controls would be preferable but they are very likely to be
correlated to our existing controls and it is hard to imagine an omitted variable related to
differential returns but completely uncorrelated with our economic controls. Thus, while these
regressions do not completely rule out low returns as an explanation, they do suggest that returns
alone are likely not driving the fraction Muslim result.
Another potential explanation could be the interaction between colonial policies and
fraction Muslim. British officials were cognizant of the substantial differences between Hindu
and Muslim educational outcomes in certain provinces and they adopted a variety of policies to
increase enrollment rates and literacy in Muslim dominant districts. As part of these policies,
15
We do not report coefficients on the individual controls, but they are available upon request.
16
Muslim students were eligible for scholarships and reduced fees in public schools, and the
colonial government established a number of schools in Muslim majority districts (Progress of
Education in India, Quinquennial Reviews, 1897-1927).
This suggests that colonial policies would make it more unlikely to find a negative
coefficient on the fraction Muslim variable in the Muslim literacy regressions because of the
larger presence of public schools. Table 4 includes per-capita public educational expenditures by
rural district boards as a control variable and the findings confirm this hypothesis. Although rural
district board expenditures do not capture total public spending on education, they were an
important category of public investments and accounted for almost 75 percent of public spending
on rural primary education. The coefficient on fraction Muslim in table 4 is lower in the
specification without province FE (column 2), but the coefficient on fraction Muslim (column 6)
is comparable to table 3A and higher than table 2A in specifications that control for province FE.
Moreover, our socio-economic variables appear to soak up most of the variation associated with
public investments in the within province comparisons, as the coefficients on Muslim are similar
across tables 3A and 4. We do not report the results separately for the 10 to 20 aged literacy rate
or the gender-specific rates, but the results on fraction Muslim are robust to including public
educational expenditures for those outcomes as well. Table 4 thus broadly confirms that public
investments are not driving the negative effect of fraction Muslim on Muslim literacy.
[INSERT TABLE 4 HERE]
Another potential channel from fraction Muslim to lower literacy is that districts with
larger Muslim populations may have lower Muslim enrollment due to the unavailability of
schools. A related hypothesis is that there may be comparable enrollment between Hindus and
Muslims, but Muslims may attend certain kind of schools that are not effective at increasing
17
literacy. To shed light on these possibilities, we collected data on different school-types and
Muslim enrollment rates for a subset of districts where the data were available.
16
In table 5, we
explore the relationship between fraction Muslim and the different school-types in the colonial
period and the results broadly confirm the historical evidence on colonial policy. Fraction
Muslim is positively correlated with public schools that were set up by the colonial government,
negatively correlated with recognized private schools, and positively correlated with
unrecognized Qur’an reading schools.
[INSERT TABLE 5 HERE]
The regressions suggest that the presence of Muslims has a negative effect on literacy
despite being positively associated with greater per-capita public schooling. One explanation for
lower Muslim literacy in Muslim dominant districts may be that they contain a smaller number
of recognized private schools; Chaudhary (2009a) finds that recognized schools were positively
correlated with subsequent literacy compared to unrecognized schools. Moreover, table 5 shows
that Muslims were more likely to establish religious schools as opposed to recognized private
schools with secular curricula. Since Muslim enrollment rates were also smaller in districts with
a larger proportion of Muslims, this suggests that areas with more Muslims had fewer schools
and the wrong types of schools from a literacy perspective. That is, fewer Muslims attended any
school in districts with more Muslims and they were more likely to attend either religious
schools or public government schools.
17
16
The data on public and private schools is reported for districts in Bengal, Bihar and Orissa, Bombay, Madras and
Punjab. Information on Qur’an schools was only available for Bengal and Bihar and Orissa. The number of Muslim
students was reported for Bengal, Bihar and Orissa, and Bombay. The main results on fraction Muslim and Muslim
literacy hold for the sample of districts with the more detailed school data. These results are available upon request.
17
However, the public schools may not have conferred substantial benefits to Muslim literacy because they were
often secondary schools that were not as strongly associated with higher literacy in this period relative to primary
schools (Chaudhary 2009a).
18
The presence of other Muslims remains significantly correlated with Muslim literacy
even after accounting for social and developmental differences across districts and the effects of
colonial policies. How should we interpret this finding? The above analysis on schools offers a
potential mechanism linking the two, namely highly Muslim regions had fewer schools that were
positively associated with literacy. This begs a larger question: why did Muslim dominant
districts contain fewer schools that promoted literacy (after controlling for social and
development characteristics)? Are there certain institutional features that discouraged the
provision of such schools in highly Muslim regions? If so, the “fraction Muslim” variable could
be a proxy for a broader institutional relationship that undermined the development of human
capital. In the following section we investigate one such institutional relationship (between
Islamic political and religious authorities) which may have had a salient effect on incentives to
acquire education.
THE LASTING EFFECTS OF RELIGIOUS AND POLITICAL INSTITUTIONS
The observed differences in literacy rates may be a result of institutional arrangements
that the previous regressions do not account for. In particular, educational institutions in regions
where Islamic religious authorities were historically strong may have provided a strong
disincentive for Muslims to attain skills that promote literacy while perhaps simultaneously
crowding in Hindus to the public school system.
The logic underlying this hypothesis follows implicitly from Rubin (2009), who analyzes
the legitimizing function of Muslim religious authorities vis-à-vis political authorities.
18
Rubin
suggests that a high degree of dependence on religious authorities entails a situation in which
18
For more on the role that religious authorities have played in legitimizing the state in the Islamic world, see Greif
(2002), Rubin (2009), Coşgel, Miceli, and Ahmed (2009), and Coşgel, Miceli, and Rubin (2009). For more on
Hinduism as a legitimizing force in India in Colonial India, see Buultjens (1986).
19
economically inhibitive laws and norms, such as those discouraging literacy, became self-
enforcing: there was less incentive for individuals to transgress religious dictates (since doing so
involved both worldly and other-worldly costs) which in turn placed little pressure on political
and religious authorities to update laws and doctrine. In turn, there were few avenues through
which such societies could “escape” inhibitive equilibria.
This logic may shed light on the case of the colonial India. Previous Muslim rulers in
India, especially the Mughals, had roots closely tied to previous Middle Eastern empires, sharing
institutions, learned languages, ideology, and ruling personnel (Metcalf 1982; Eaton 1993;
Kozlowski 1995). Like other Islamic rulers, Mughal leadership was based on what Greif (2002)
calls “faith-based legitimacy”, whereby political rule was legitimate only when it complied with
Islamic dictates.
19
This entailed a situation in which Muslim religious authorities had some
power vis-à-vis political authorities, though the latter dominated for much of the Mughal reign.
One way that this dynamic manifested itself was through significant donations, often via the
waqf, given to religious authorities and institutions by political authorities in order to legitimate
their power (Kozlowski 1985, 1995; Eaton 1993).
20
This encouraged further donations by the
nobility, gentry, and merchants and hence greatly increased the scope of religious power.
In India, this relationship became especially important in the 18
th
century, when the
Mughal Empire began to decline. In the ensuing power vacuum, religious authorities were easily
able to step in and increase their power, entailing a dramatic expansion of their prerogatives in
relation to social, economic, and educational institutions. British policies facilitated this change,
as they promoted the use of Islamic law for Muslims. Although some aspects of British law
19
Anderson (1993) and Eaton (1993) stress the importance of abiding by Muslim dictates for maintaining legitimacy
amongst Islamic leaders in India.
20
Funding of religious schools has been an important legitimizing force throughout Islamic history. For more, see
Kozlowski (1995) and Berkey (2007).
20
eventually prevailed, the ‘ulama (legal-religious scholars) were the only group who could fill this
void in the absence of a Muslim state (Metcalf 1982, ch. 1-2; Anderson 1993).
One result of this institutional heritage was a marked increase in Islamic schools
(madrasahs, maktabs, and Qur’an reading schools) in areas formerly ruled by Muslims. Although
the curriculum of these schools varied widely throughout India, anecdotal evidence suggests that
these schools encouraged the ability to read and write to a much lesser extent than the public
schools established by colonial authorities. Many of these schools promoted Qur’an
memorization and recitation of other religious sciences instead of skills associated with literacy
(Kozlowski 1985).
21
This was a result of the significance of oral transmission in Islamic history,
which was the most important means by which religious scholars maintained their monopoly on
knowledge (Eaton 1993; Berkey 2007).
22
Islamic schools were popular in many parts of India
and were able to support themselves using private contributions instead of British grant-in-aids,
which would have permitted the British control over the curriculum (Metcalf 1982, ch.3). This
permitted religious learning to remain the core of the curriculum since the British policy of
religious neutrality meant that formal religious study was supposed to be excluded from
instruction in publicly funded schools (Zaman 1999).
Theoretically, this phenomenon has two implications. For one, it suggests that Muslim
literacy should be lower in areas where Islamic (and especially Mughal) political authorities
21
This by no means entails that all Islamic schools discouraged literacy or even those that did never offered
anything in the curriculum which would promote literacy. Though this was particularly true of the Deobandi school
that Metcalf (1982) analyzed in great detail. Indeed, Metcalf (1982), Kozlowski (1985), and Zaman (1999) show
instances of Islamic schools which promoted literacy. However, on the margin, the probability of a student
becoming literate who attended a public funded school must have been greater than one who attended an Islamic
school, for reasons provided above. For example, the British formed the ill-fated Delhi College in 1825 because the
private madrasahs spent too much time on the Qur’an and there was no regular system of attendance (Metcalf 1982).
The British did sponsor some madrasahs, as long as the content of the curriculum was deemed sufficiently “useful”
(Zaman 1999).
22
Eaton (1993, p. 296) provides anecdotal evidence that many Indian mullās themselves could not read, but that
they were understood by the villagers to be tapping into a deeper, otherworldly source of power.
21
dominated in the past. This may help explain the result that Muslim literacy rate is negatively
associated with the presence of other Muslims, as regions formerly ruled by Muslims have
somewhat higher Muslim populations (the correlation between years of Muslim rule and fraction
Muslim is 0.206). Moreover, because these schools primarily relied on private donations, they
needed a sufficiently large (and wealthy) Muslim population for financial support. The other
implication is that this phenomenon may have “crowded in” Hindus into the public school
system. With more Muslims going to private Muslim schools, public money may have been
diverted toward non-Muslim students, which could help explain the positive coefficient on
fraction Muslim in the Hindu literacy regressions. These predictions are aligned with
Kozlowski’s (1985, p. 64-65) insights:
In the second half of the nineteenth century … Hindus began to abandon some of
the traditions of the Mughal elite and enrol (sic) in schools established on the
British model which concentrated on learning English. … [D]espite the
competition from “modern” schools, many Muslims continued to send their sons
to schools which taught the old curriculum by the old methods of recitation and
memorization.
To test this hypothesis, we construct a new variable, “years of Muslim rule” using maps
from Robinson (1982, p. 59, 113), who delineates the range for the years of onset of Muslim rule
and the years of conclusion of Muslim rule throughout British India.
23
We employ the average
beginning and end date in our regressions, but the results are robust to using lower or upper
bounds of Muslim rule. Summary statistics of this variable broken down by province are shown
in Table 6.
[INSERT TABLE 6 HERE]
23
The dates for the onset of Muslim rule are pre-1530, 1530-1605, and 1605-1707. The dates for the cessation of
Muslim rule are pre-1765, 1765-1805, and post-1805. We assume that the upper bound for the onset of Muslim rule
begins in 1200 and the upper bound for the cessation of Muslim rule is 1850.
22
We employ this variable as a proxy for the entrenchment of Muslim political authority.
The logic laid out above suggests that where Muslim political authority were entrenched,
religious authorities were also propagated, permitting them to enter the power vacuum left by the
fall of the Mughals. In turn, schools which discouraged literacy should be more prevalent in
these regions, since these schools were established by religious authorities to maintain their
monopoly over religious learning and thus maintain their position vis-à-vis secular authorities.
Tables 7A through 7C report the findings on Hindu and Muslim literacy controlling for
years of Muslim rule and the same set of socio-economic variables as in tables 3A through 3C.
We find in all regressions (except for those on female literacy) that the years of Muslim rule has
a negative and significant effect on literacy. That is, a legacy of Muslim rule entails a situation in
which incentive to attain literacy is diminished. Moreover, the results also confirm other testable
predictions arising from the suggested link between Muslim rule and literacy. For one, the
coefficient on Muslim rule in the Hindu literacy regression is positive and significant in the 1921
cross-section after accounting for province fixed effects, suggesting that Hindus may have been
“crowded in” to the public school system where Muslims ruled. This result follows from the
above logic because it is in these regions that Muslims chose private schools while the British
provided greater funding for public schools. Moreover, these results are robust to within
province or across province comparisons. As seen in table 6, the within province variation in
length of Muslim rule is relatively small relative to the across province variation, which suggests
that even though intra-province variation is much less than inter-province variation, small
differences in years of Muslim rule has a salient effect on literacy rates.
[INSERT TABLES 7A, 7B AND 7C HERE]
23
The coefficients on fraction Muslim, while still significant in many of these regressions,
have a smaller magnitude and significance level in all regressions (except for female literacy)
compared to those in tables 3A-3C (which are the same as 7A-7C but without the years of
Muslim rule variable). In the fixed effect regressions (column 6 in table 7A and 7B, column 2 in
table 7C), the coefficient on fraction Muslim drops between 29% and 49% compared to
regressions in which years of Muslim rule is not employed as a control. Hence, although the
addition of this control does not eliminate the importance of the presence of Muslims on literacy,
it significantly diminishes the importance of this coefficient.
The findings on gender-specific literacy are also of interest. An increase of 100 years of
Muslim rule translates into a 0.26 to 0.30 percentage point decrease in male literacy, which is
non-trivial considering that some regions of India were subject to Muslim rule for over five
centuries. On the other hand, Muslim rule does not have a significant effect on literacy for
Muslim or Hindu females. This is expected – the religious schools that attracted Muslim youths
(and discouraged literacy) were almost solely open to males. Hence, the pathway through which
Muslim rule affects literacy should only affect male literacy, not female literacy. The regressions
thus confirm the testable predictions arising from the historical narrative: length of Muslim rule
negatively affected male Muslim literacy, positively affected Hindu literacy, and did not affect
female literacy.
Years of Muslim rule is an admittedly crude proxy for the pathway by which a “legacy of
dependence” permitted religious authorities to usurp power and thus promote schools that
discouraged literacy. There are numerous cultural, economic, religious, and militaristic
phenomena associated with years of Muslim rule that are not associated with the pathway
proposed in this paper. However, we view the use of this proxy as a successful first-order attempt
24
at showing that broader, institutional features may underlie the diverging paths of human capital
accumulation between groups rather than purely cultural factors. Though there are possibly other
ways that “years of Muslim rule” may affect literacy rates in the 20th century, we believe that the
institutional pathway that we propose in this section is the most reasonable one. Although these
results highlight the need of a more nuanced, formally modeled and specified approach, this
exercise suggests that we can start chipping away at explanations relying on cultural
explanations with even the bluntest of institutional controls.
BROADER SIGNIFICANCE
Differences in human capital accumulation are vital components of differences in broader
economic outcomes both across countries and across different groups within the same country. In
this paper, we attempt to shed light on the conditions under which Muslims (a minority group)
attained less human capital than Hindus (the majority group) in early 20th-century India. Are the
factors leading to these differences cultural, institutional, demographic, or something else?
Our baseline specifications suggest that Muslim literacy rates are negatively associated
with the presence of other Muslims in the district. This result is robust to various social,
economic, and educational controls, although adding these controls weakens the result. We also
suggest that the institutional history of the region may have played a role in discouraging literacy
amongst Muslims. Our analysis shows that this history did indeed play a salient role in
determining literacy rates, but it does not completely eliminate the negative Muslim effect on
Muslim literacy.
What, then, can account for this result? Is there something “inherent in Islam” that
discourages economically beneficial actions (as those in the Weberian school believe), or are our
25
results not capturing all of the salient features that affect literacy? We urge extreme caution in
accepting the former view, and instead side with the latter. One major reason we are not ready to
accept purely cultural explanations is that data constraints prevent us from testing two important
avenues which may have affected Muslim literacy. First, the regional variation in fraction
Muslim could be reflective of the positive conversion of Muslims in certain parts of the
subcontinent, which continues to influence educational outcomes as late as the 20
th
century. If
lower caste Hindus converted to Islam in order to escape the social and economic degradation
imposed by the caste system, then it may be the case that Muslims have poor economic status
(and hence less access to human capital) because individuals of lower socio-economic status
selected into Islam, not the other way around.
24
Our development variables can only partially
control for this phenomenon – we have data at the district level, but it is not delineated by
religion. This hypothesis suggests that at least part of our result may stem from a negative
selection of Muslims in Muslim-dominant districts, and that we should control for Muslim
occupational structure within a district instead of average district-level occupational structures.
Future research should shed light on the importance of this hypothesis.
Second, we stress that our institutional proxy, “years of Muslim rule”, is extremely noisy.
The number of years that a district was subject to Muslim rule may entail any number of
phenomena, though we argue (through analytical narrative and anecdotal evidence) that the most
salient and direct effect of this variable was discouraging Muslim literacy via the promotion of
Islamic schools. Thus, while we suggest that the “fraction Muslim” variable may be a proxy for
this phenomenon, our variable on years of Muslim rule is yet another proxy albeit a more precise
one. Indeed, the great degree of significance on the years of Muslim rule coefficient, even
24
It is unlikely that selection bias arose from migration of Muslims, as migration levels were very low in British
India.
26
controlling for province fixed effects, suggests that this variable (and in turn the institutional
arrangement it proxies for) is a salient factor in determining Muslim literacy. A more direct
measure of historical political and religious institutions would help shed more light on this
relationship, but must be left for future research, as data constraints currently prohibit us from
creating such a variable.
In sum, we view this paper as a first step in understanding the factors which affect human
capital accumulation across different groups. We are able to chip away at cultural explanations
that could rely on the argument, “where there are more Muslims, there are worse economic
outcomes.” We show that controlling for socio-economic variables and particularly institutional
variables helps reduce, but not eliminate, the effect of the presence of Muslims on Muslim
literacy. More broadly, this analysis suggests that the “long hand of history” has played some
role in subsequent differences in literacy rates through the persistence of institutions which
discouraged literacy. However, we cannot at the moment say just how large of a role this
institutional history has played. To do this, we need a more nuanced approach that analyzes the
direct pathways linking institutional history to literacy outcomes, which we leave for future
research.
REFERENCES
Anderson, Michael R. “Islamic Law and the Colonial Encounter in British India.” In: Institutions
and Ideologies: A SOAS South Asia Reader, Eds. David Arnold and Peter Robb. London:
Curzon Press, 1993, 165-85
Basu, Aparna. The Growth of Education and Political Development in India 1898–1920. Delhi:
Oxford University Press, 1974.
_________. Essays in the History of Indian Education. New Delhi: Concept, 1982.
Berkey, Jonathan P. “Madrasas Medieval and Modern: Politics, Education, and the Problem of
Muslim Identity.” In: Schooling Islam: The Culture and Politics of Modern Muslim
27
Education, Ed. Robert W. Hefner and Muhammad Qasim Zaman. Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 2007, 40-60.
Buultjens, Ralph. “India: Religion, Political Legitimacy, and the Secular State.” Annals of the
American Academy of Political and Social Science, 483 (Jan. 1986): 93-109
Chaudhary, Latika. "Determinants of Primary Schooling in British India." Journal of Economic
History 69, No. 1 (2009a): 269-302.
_________. “Indian Elites and English Literacy: A Historical Examination of Public and Private
Funding of Education.” Working paper, Stanford University, March 2009b.
Coşgel, Metin, Thomas Miceli, and Rasha Ahmed. “Law, State Power, and Taxation in Islamic
History.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, forthcoming, 2009.
Coşgel, Metin, Thomas Miceli, and Jared Rubin. ‘Guns and Books: Legitimacy, Revolt, and
Technological Change in the Ottoman Empire.’ Working Paper, 2009.
Drèze, Jean and Amartya Sen. India: Economic Development and Social Opportunity. Delhi:
Oxford University Press, 1998.
Eaton, Richard. The Rise of Islam and the Bengal Frontier, 1204-1760. Berkeley: University of
California Press, 1993.
Fernandez, Raquel and Dani Rodrick. “Resistance to Reform: Status Quo Bias in the Presence of
Individual-Specific Uncertainty.” American Economic Review 81, no. 5 (1991): 1146-55.
Fryer, Roland, and David Austen-Smith. "An Economic Analysis of 'Acting White'." Quarterly
Journal of Economics 120, no. 2 (May 2005): 551-83.
Galor, Oded and Omer Moav. “Das Human-Kapital: A Theory of the Demise of the Class
Structure.” Review of Economic Studies 73, no. (2006): 85-117.
Ghosh, Suresh C. The History of Education in Modern India 1757-1998. New Delhi: Orient
Longman, 2000.
Ghurye, G. S. Caste, Class and Occupation. Bombay: Popular Book Depot, 1961.
Greif, Avner. ‘The Islamic Equilibrium: Legitimacy and Political, Social, and Economic
Outcomes,’ Working Paper, Stanford University, 2002.
Hanuskeh, Eric A, John F Kaln, and Steven G Rivkin. "New Evidence about Brown v. Board of
Education: The Complex Effects of School Racial Composition on Achievement."
Working paper, 2004.
House of Commons. “Despatch to Government of India on General Education in India.”
Sessional Papers, 1854, paper 393, vol. XLVII, p.155.
28
_________.“Progress of Education in India, 1892-97 (Third Quinquennial Review).” Sessional
Papers, 1899, paper C.9190, vol. LXV, p.501.
_________. “Review of Progress of Education in India, 1897-98 to 1901-02. Fourth
Quinquennial Review (East India: Education).” Sessional Papers, 1904, paper Cd. 2181,
2182, vol. LXV, p.1.
_________. “Progress of Education in India, 1902-1907. Fifth Quinquennial Review (East India:
Education).” Sessional Papers, 1909, paper Cd. 4635, 4636, vol. LXIII, p.1.
_________. “Progress of Education in India, 1907-12. Sixth Quinquennial Review (East India:
Education).” Sessional Papers, 1914, paper Cd. 7485, 7486, vol. LXII, p.1.
_________. “Seventh Quinquennial Review, 1912-1917 (East India: Education).” Sessional
Papers, 1919, paper Cmd. 256, 257, vol. XXVIII, p.1.
India. Census of India, 1911. Calcutta: Office of the Superintendent of Government Printing,
India, 1913.
_________. Census of India, 1921. Delhi: Office of the Superintendent of Government Printing,
India, 1923.
_________. India, district and provincial gazetteers. Zug, Switzerland: Inter Documentation,
1979.
Kozlowski, Gregory C. Muslim Endowments and Society in British India. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1985.
_________. “Imperial Authority, Benefactions and Endowments (Awqāf) in Mughal India.”
Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient, 38, no. 3 (1995): 355-70
Kumar, Dharma, ed. The Cambridge Economic History of India vol. 2. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1982.
Margo, Robert. Race and Schooling in the South, 1880-1950: An Economic History. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1990.
Metcalf, Barbara Daly. Islamic Revival in British India: Deoband, 1860-1900. Princeton,
Princeton University Press, 1982.
Nurullah, Syed and J.P. Naik. A History of Education in India (During the British Period).
London: Macmillan, 1951.
Rajan, Raghuram. “Rent Preservation and the Persistence of Underdevelopment.” American
Economic Journals: Macroeconomics, forthcoming.
29
Richey, James A. Progress of education in India, 1917-1922. Calcutta: Superintendent of
Government Press, 1924.
Robinson, Francis. Atlas of the Islamic World Since 1500. New York: Facts on File, 1982.
Rubin, Jared. “Institutions, the Rise of Commerce, and the Persistence of Laws: Interest
Restrictions in Islam & Christianity.” Working paper, California State University,
Fullerton, 2009.
Schultz, Theodore W. Transforming Traditional Agriculture. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1983
Srinivas, Mysore Narasimhachar. Village, Caste, Gender and Method: Essays in Indian Social
Anthropoligy. New York: Oxford University Press, 1998.
Zaman, Muhammad Qasim. “Religious Education and the Rhetoric of Reform: the Madrasa in
British India and Pakistan.” Comparative Studies in Society and History 41, (1999): 294-
323.
30
TABLES
TABLE 1: SUMMARY STATISTICS
Hindu Muslim
Variable Obs. Mean Std Dev Obs Mean Std Dev
Literacy Rate 410 7.4% 5.6% 396 6.8% 5.2%
Assam 16 7.0% 2.0% 13 5.2% 3.2%
Bengal 54 11.9% 3.5% 52 5.8% 2.8%
Bihar and Orissa 42 4.5% 1.4% 38 5.9% 3.8%
Bombay and Sind 49 9.2% 5.6% 49 8.3% 5.7%
Central Provinces 44 4.3% 1.4% 39 11.9% 4.2%
Madras 50 8.3% 4.7% 50 12.3% 6.1%
Punjab 59 11.5% 9.1% 59 2.6% 3.4%
United Provinces 96 3.6% 1.5% 96 4.6% 2.8%
Population Share 410 69.7% 27.3% 410 23.6% 26.2%
Assam 16 64.9% 13.3% 16 20.4% 18.9%
Bengal 54 46.0% 23.1% 54 47.4% 26.5%
Bihar and Orissa 42 81.2% 17.3% 42 9.0% 8.5%
Bombay and Sind 49 71.1% 29.3% 49 25.9% 30.3%
Central Provinces 44 80.7% 13.2% 44 4.2% 2.7%
Madras 50 89.0% 7.6% 50 6.7% 6.3%
Punjab 59 33.1% 26.5% 59 55.8% 26.7%
United Provinces 96 85.3% 8.6% 96 13.7% 8.0%
1911 1921
Hindu Literacy Rate 204 7.1% 6.2% 206 7.7% 5.0%
Muslim Literacy Rate 195 6.2% 4.8% 201 7.3% 5.6%
Fraction Hindu 204 69.9% 27.2% 206 69.4% 27.4%
Fraction Brahman 204 5.0% 4.3% 206 5.0% 4.3%
Fraction Low Castes 204 15.8% 8.1% 206 14.5% 8.3%
Fraction Muslim 204 23.2% 26.2% 206 23.9% 26.3%
Fraction Christian 204 1.0% 2.0% 206 1.2% 2.2%
Fraction Tribes 204 3.7% 9.5% 206 3.3% 8.5%
Caste and Religious Fragmentation 204 0.74 0.18 206 0.73 0.19
Fraction Urban 204 9.9% 10.5% 206 10.9% 11.5%
Fraction Commercial 204 7.0% 3.6% 206 6.7% 3.2%
Fraction Industry 204 12.2% 6.3% 206 11.6% 6.4%
Fraction Professionals 204 1.6% 0.9% 206 1.6% 1.2%
Income Tax Revenues per-capita 200 0.06 0.10 200 0.20 0.64
Source: Census of India (1911 and 1921) and Imperial District Gazetteer Series (income tax revenues per-capita variable).
See text for more details on dataset.
31
TABLE 2A: TOTAL LITERACY RATES
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim
1911 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu -0.056* -0.047 -0.269 0.266*** -0.054* -0.036 -0.274 0.084
[0.030] [0.032] [0.279] [0.086] [0.028] [0.030] [0.305] [0.134]
Fraction Muslim 0.095*** -0.141*** 0.01 -0.477*** 0.085*** -0.126*** 0.014 -0.355***
[0.020] [0.033] [0.126] [0.079] [0.023] [0.028] [0.160] [0.080]
Fraction Hindu
2
0.176 -0.250*** 0.184 -0.102
[0.199] [0.081] [0.224] [0.110]
Fraction Muslim
2
0.079 0.458*** 0.057 0.276***
[0.208] [0.077] [0.245] [0.093]
Province FE No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 204 195 204 195 204 195 204 195
Adj. R-squared 0.39 0.28 0.43 0.38 0.45 0.50 0.48 0.54
1921 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu 0.001 -0.073* 0.185** 0.316*** 0.009 -0.025 0.111 0.116
[0.013] [0.037] [0.087] [0.089] [0.015] [0.030] [0.094] [0.146]
Fraction Muslim 0.127*** -0.184*** -0.111** -0.606*** 0.124*** -0.135*** -0.095** -0.419***
[0.015] [0.038] [0.048] [0.074] [0.017] [0.028] [0.047] [0.081]
Fraction Hindu
2
-0.146** -0.314*** -0.082 -0.125
[0.065] [0.077] [0.071] [0.117]
Fraction Muslim
2
0.323*** 0.575*** 0.268*** 0.337***
[0.063] [0.072] [0.066] [0.092]
Province FE No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 206 201 206 201 206 201 206 201
Adj. R-squared 0.43 0.30 0.49 0.42 0.59 0.52 0.63 0.57
Robust standard errors in brackets, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
32
TABLE 2B: LITERACY RATES FOR THE POPULATION AGED 10 TO 20
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim
1911 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu -0.055 -0.059 -0.176 0.326*** -0.047 -0.04 -0.265 0.039
[0.033] [0.039] [0.304] [0.096] [0.034] [0.034] [0.349] [0.128]
Fraction Muslim 0.104*** -0.171*** -0.006 -0.574*** 0.098*** -0.139*** 0.042 -0.381***
[0.023] [0.040] [0.135] [0.089] [0.029] [0.033] [0.171] [0.086]
Fraction Hindu
2
0.103 -0.307*** 0.181 -0.072
[0.217] [0.090] [0.254] [0.108]
Fraction Muslim
2
0.124 0.552*** 0.039 0.279***
[0.224] [0.085] [0.267] [0.093]
Province FE No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 204 195 204 195 204 195 204 195
Adj. R-squared 0.35 0.29 0.37 0.40 0.41 0.49 0.42 0.52
1921 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu -0.009 -0.109** 0.209* 0.375*** 0.004 -0.026 0.051 0.066
[0.018] [0.048] [0.121] [0.110] [0.019] [0.034] [0.134] [0.154]
Fraction Muslim 0.142*** -0.236*** -0.113* -0.751*** 0.137*** -0.145*** -0.052 -0.429***
[0.021] [0.050] [0.063] [0.102] [0.021] [0.032] [0.069] [0.096]
Fraction Hindu
2
-0.173* -0.390*** -0.038 -0.087
[0.089] [0.096] [0.101] [0.127]
Fraction Muslim
2
0.349*** 0.702*** 0.226** 0.327***
[0.087] [0.098] [0.097] [0.105]
Province FE No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 206 201 206 201 206 201 206 201
Adj. R-squared 0.40 0.28 0.44 0.42 0.56 0.53 0.58 0.56
Robust standard errors in brackets, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
33
TABLE 2C: MALE AND FEMALE LITERACY RATES
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Male Female
Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim
1911 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu -0.032 -0.05 0.131 0.054 -0.07 -0.003 -0.782 0.005
[0.024] [0.048] [0.119] [0.186] [0.067] [0.005] [0.783] [0.031]
Fraction Muslim 0.185*** -0.206*** -0.315*** -0.562*** -0.028 -0.018*** 0.429 -0.052***
[0.031] [0.045] [0.078] [0.120] [0.050] [0.005] [0.401] [0.016]
Fraction Hindu
2
-0.119 -0.097 0.574 -0.008
[0.097] [0.156] [0.571] [0.025]
Fraction Muslim
2
0.615*** 0.409*** -0.633 0.039**
[0.107] [0.135] [0.623] [0.019]
Province FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 204 195 204 195 204 195 204 195
Adj. R-squared 0.57 0.55 0.66 0.58 0.01 0.29 0.04 0.31
1921 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu 0.049* -0.028 0.188 0.093 -0.019 -0.011 0.047 0.04
[0.027] [0.048] [0.146] [0.190] [0.017] [0.010] [0.043] [0.056]
Fraction Muslim 0.222*** -0.210*** -0.170** -0.645*** 0.018 -0.034*** -0.018 -0.106***
[0.030] [0.045] [0.079] [0.118] [0.016] [0.009] [0.033] [0.030]
Fraction Hindu
2
-0.113 -0.119 -0.053 -0.044
[0.111] [0.155] [0.036] [0.046]
Fraction Muslim
2
0.476*** 0.496*** 0.051 0.088**
[0.109] [0.127] [0.034] [0.035]
Province FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 206 201 206 201 206 201 206 201
Adj. R-squared 0.59 0.56 0.64 0.60 0.35 0.32 0.35 0.34
Robust standard errors in brackets, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
34
TABLE 3A: ARE LOW RETURNS CONTRIBUTING TO LOWER MUSLIM LITERACY?
TOTAL LITERACY RATES
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim
1911 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu -0.061 0.081*** -0.463 0.310*** -0.05 0.000 -0.606 0.000
[0.176] [0.027] [0.481] [0.117] [0.173] [0.033] [0.614] [0.099]
Fraction Muslim -0.004 -0.080** 0.256 -0.542*** 0.007 -0.140*** 0.305 -0.361**
[0.162] [0.037] [0.303] [0.164] [0.164] [0.050] [0.477] [0.150]
Fraction Hindu
2
0.416 -0.312** 0.549 -0.054
[0.389] [0.134] [0.546] [0.114]
Fraction Muslim
2
-0.175 0.456*** -0.232 0.229*
[0.371] [0.158] [0.542] [0.137]
Observations 200 193 200 193 200 193 200 193
Adj. R-squared 0.52 0.56 0.55 0.58 0.51 0.65 0.55 0.67
1921 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu 0.052 0.036 0.094 0.338*** 0.025 -0.024 -0.029 -0.004
[0.055] [0.029] [0.089] [0.127] [0.054] [0.042] [0.078] [0.108]
Fraction Muslim 0.124** -0.159*** -0.067 -0.773*** 0.081 -0.204*** -0.195 -0.466***
[0.062] [0.043] [0.127] [0.192] [0.061] [0.054] [0.122] [0.170]
Fraction Hindu
2
-0.085 -0.421*** -0.023 -0.084
[0.090] [0.150] [0.087] [0.124]
Fraction Muslim
2
0.194** 0.582*** 0.282*** 0.258*
[0.094] [0.179] [0.094] [0.153]
Observations 200 197 200 197 200 197 200 197
Adj. R-squared 0.75 0.57 0.76 0.60 0.80 0.67 0.83 0.68
Province FE No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Social Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Development Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Robust standard errors in brackets, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Social controls include the population share of Christians, tribes, Buddhists and CRFI. Development controls include income taxes per-capita,
urbanization rate, a dummy for coastal districts, population share supported by commerce, population share supported by industry and
population share supported by professionals. See text for details.
35
TABLE 3B: ARE LOW RETURNS CONTRIBUTING TO LOWER MUSLIM LITERACY?
LITERACY RATES POPULATION AGED 10 TO 20
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim
1911 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu -0.04 0.107*** -0.481 0.402*** -0.068 0.004 -0.764 -0.014
[0.190] [0.038] [0.513] [0.147] [0.191] [0.045] [0.648] [0.116]
Fraction Muslim 0.037 -0.071 0.325 -0.718*** -0.002 -0.145** 0.386 -0.456**
[0.176] [0.052] [0.330] [0.208] [0.183] [0.072] [0.508] [0.195]
Fraction Hindu
2
0.457 -0.415** 0.69 -0.061
[0.417] [0.169] [0.576] [0.136]
Fraction Muslim
2
-0.194 0.648*** -0.304 0.325*
[0.397] [0.200] [0.571] [0.171]
Observations 200 193 200 193 200 193 200 193
Adj. R-squared 0.49 0.48 0.51 0.52 0.48 0.57 0.54 0.60
1921 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu 0.023 0.009 0.122 0.462** -0.011 -0.043 -0.125 -0.021
[0.071] [0.038] [0.122] [0.180] [0.078] [0.051] [0.121] [0.147]
Fraction Muslim 0.12 -0.214*** -0.172 -1.145*** 0.066 -0.239*** -0.217 -0.575**
[0.081] [0.055] [0.166] [0.276] [0.085] [0.067] [0.168] [0.225]
Fraction Hindu
2
-0.16 -0.635*** 0.028 -0.104
[0.125] [0.213] [0.124] [0.169]
Fraction Muslim
2
0.289** 0.883*** 0.298** 0.332
[0.128] [0.253] [0.133] [0.201]
Observations 200 197 200 197 200 197 200 197
Adj. R-squared 0.71 0.47 0.71 0.52 0.76 0.62 0.79 0.63
Province FE No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Social Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Development Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Robust standard errors in brackets, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Social controls include the population share of Christians, tribes, Buddhists and CRFI. Development controls include income taxes per-capita,
urbanization rate, a dummy for coastal districts, population share supported by commerce, population share supported by industry and
population share supported by professionals. See text for details.
36
TABLE 3C: ARE LOW RETURNS CONTRIBUTING TO LOWER MUSLIM LITERACY?
MALE AND FEMALE LITERACY
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Male Female
Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim
1911 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu 0.253** 0.036 0.267* -0.017 -0.43 -0.003 -1.365 -0.005
[0.103] [0.061] [0.143] [0.171] [0.453] [0.005] [1.189] [0.018]
Fraction Muslim 0.304** -0.194** -0.403** -0.570** -0.366 -0.032*** 0.800 -0.060***
[0.120] [0.092] [0.195] [0.263] [0.419] [0.008] [0.707] [0.023]
Fraction Hindu
2
-0.184 -0.045 1.105 -0.004
[0.138] [0.197] [0.944] [0.020]
Fraction Muslim
2
0.726*** 0.396 -1.034 0.033
[0.161] [0.243] [0.897] [0.023]
Observations 200 193 200 193 200 193 200 193
Adj. R-squared 0.77 0.64 0.82 0.66 0.04 0.53 0.09 0.54
1921 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu 0.07 -0.012 0.054 -0.031 -0.002 -0.030** -0.059 -0.011
[0.093] [0.071] [0.131] [0.179] [0.017] [0.013] [0.043] [0.037]
Fraction Muslim 0.132 -0.312*** -0.421** -0.741** 0.03 -0.077*** 0.031 -0.133**
[0.105] [0.088] [0.193] [0.289] [0.020] [0.019] [0.059] [0.052]
Fraction Hindu
2
-0.126 -0.091 0.051 -0.031
[0.139] [0.206] [0.046] [0.042]
Fraction Muslim
2
0.554*** 0.43 0.007 0.053
[0.156] [0.262] [0.049] [0.046]
Observations 200 197 200 197 200 197 200 197
Adj. R-squared 0.78 0.66 0.82 0.67 0.60 0.54 0.61 0.54
Province FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Social Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Development Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Robust standard errors in brackets, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Social controls include the population share of Christians, tribes, Buddhists and CRFI. Development controls include income taxes per-capita,
urbanization rate, a dummy for coastal districts, population share supported by commerce, population share supported by industry and
population share supported by professionals. See text for details.
37
TABLE 4: CONTROLLING FOR PUBLIC EXPENDITURES ON EDUCATION
TOTAL LITERACY RATES
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim
1911 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu -0.047 0.079*** -0.5 0.302** -0.049 -0.003 -0.663 0.003
[0.175] [0.029] [0.517] [0.131] [0.177] [0.035] [0.652] [0.110]
Fraction Muslim 0.015 -0.077* 0.362 -0.545*** 0.011 -0.141*** 0.379 -0.413**
[0.161] [0.042] [0.388] [0.195] [0.169] [0.049] [0.570] [0.165]
Fraction Hindu
2
0.487 -0.310** 0.618 -0.071
[0.447] [0.154] [0.604] [0.127]
Fraction Muslim
2
-0.242 0.456** -0.287 0.276*
[0.437] [0.178] [0.617] [0.149]
Observations 189 185 189 185 189 185 189 185
Adj. R-squared 0.52 0.56 0.55 0.58 0.51 0.66 0.56 0.68
1921 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu 0.051 0.039 0.096 0.293** 0.018 -0.015 -0.033 -0.03
[0.055] [0.029] [0.095] [0.127] [0.051] [0.040] [0.081] [0.110]
Fraction Muslim 0.116* -0.135*** -0.096 -0.683*** 0.072 -0.180*** -0.244* -0.455***
[0.064] [0.047] [0.147] [0.197] [0.059] [0.054] [0.134] [0.173]
Fraction Hindu
2
-0.092 -0.361** -0.033 -0.054
[0.106] [0.150] [0.094] [0.127]
Fraction Muslim
2
0.215* 0.516*** 0.323*** 0.277*
[0.110] [0.181] [0.109] [0.159]
Observations 187 186 187 186 187 186 187 186
Adj. R-squared 0.75 0.58 0.76 0.61 0.80 0.68 0.84 0.69
Province FE No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Education Expenditures Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Social Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Development Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Robust standard errors in brackets, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Social controls include the population share of Christians, tribes, Buddhists and CRFI. Development controls include income taxes per-capita,
urbanization rate, a dummy for coastal districts, population share supported by commerce, population share supported by industry and
population share supported by professionals. We control for public educational expenditures per-capita incurred by the rural district boards in all
the specifications. See text for details.
38
TABLE 5: FEWER SCHOOLS or WRONG SCHOOLS?
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Public Schools per-
capita
Recognized Private
Schools per-capita
Unrecognized
Koran Schools
per-capita
Muslim Students per
Muslim population
Fraction Muslim -0.235* 0.280** -0.471 -0.870*** 0.066* 0.075* -0.026*** -0.037***
[0.134] [0.135] [0.287] [0.287] [0.039] [0.043] [0.006] [0.005]
Province FE No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes
Social Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No
Income Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No
Development Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No
Observations 114 114 114 114 47 47 66 66
Adjusted R-squared 0.43 0.85 0.47 0.77 0.086 0.067 0.20 0.31
Robust standard errors in brackets, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Source: Data for 1911 cross-section only. Specifications on public schools and recognized private schools are for districts in Bengal, Bihar and
Orissa, Bombay, Madras and Punjab. This data was unreported for the other provinces. Information on the number of Koran Schools was only
available for districts in Bengal and Bihar and Orissa. The number of Muslim students was only reported for Bengal, Bihar and Orissa, and
Bombay. Social controls include the population share of Brahman, low castes, Christians, tribes, Buddhists and CRFI. Development controls
include income taxes per-capita, urbanization rate, a dummy for coastal districts, population share supported by commerce, population share
supported by industry and population share supported by professionals.
TABLE 6: SUMMARY STATISTICS
Variable Obs. Mean Std Dev
Hundreds of Years of Muslim Rule (Average) 206 2.75 1.39
Assam 8 1.69 0.00
Bengal 27 1.69 0.00
Bihar and Orissa 21 3.30 0.94
Bombay and Sind 25 1.70 0.77
Central Provinces 22 1.69 0.68
Madras 25 1.09 0.45
Punjab 30 4.20 0.31
United Provinces 48 4.28 0.29
Hundreds of Years of Muslim Rule (Upper Bound) 206 3.97 1.97
Hundreds of Years of Muslim Rule (Lower Bound) 206 1.53 0.85
Source: Robinson (1982)
39
TABLE 7A: DOES A LEGACY OF MUSLIM RULE AFFECT LITERACY?
TOTAL LITERACY RATES
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim
1911 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu -0.068 0.042* -0.566 0.054 -0.06 0.022 -0.615 0.027
[0.175] [0.025] [0.513] [0.101] [0.175] [0.036] [0.615] [0.096]
Fraction Muslim -0.005 -0.085** 0.355 -0.296** -0.013 -0.099* 0.282 -0.326**
[0.163] [0.036] [0.332] [0.137] [0.168] [0.056] [0.477] [0.144]
Fraction Hindu
2
0.516 -0.062 0.547 -0.059
[0.420] [0.116] [0.547] [0.109]
Fraction Muslim
2
-0.265 0.237* -0.228 0.235*
[0.400] [0.132] [0.542] [0.130]
Years of Muslim Rule -0.002 -0.012*** -0.005** -0.012*** 0.006 -0.011* 0.006 -0.011*
[0.001] [0.002] [0.002] [0.002] [0.004] [0.006] [0.004] [0.006]
Observations 200 193 200 193 200 193 200 193
Adj. R-squared 0.52 0.66 0.55 0.67 0.51 0.66 0.55 0.68
1921 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu 0.047 0.022 -0.001 0.12 0.011 0.006 -0.049 0.033
[0.052] [0.030] [0.086] [0.109] [0.054] [0.041] [0.078] [0.103]
Fraction Muslim 0.134** -0.135*** 0.045 -0.522*** 0.052 -0.145** -0.217* -0.416**
[0.060] [0.045] [0.133] [0.157] [0.062] [0.060] [0.122] [0.162]
Fraction Hindu
2
0.02 -0.183 -0.017 -0.092
[0.091] [0.127] [0.086] [0.119]
Fraction Muslim
2
0.106 0.389*** 0.277*** 0.266*
[0.096] [0.145] [0.094] [0.144]
Years of Muslim Rule -0.006*** -0.015*** -0.006*** -0.014*** 0.007* -0.014** 0.007** -0.014**
[0.001] [0.002] [0.002] [0.002] [0.004] [0.007] [0.003] [0.007]
Observations 200 197 200 197 200 197 200 197
Adj. R-squared 0.77 0.66 0.78 0.68 0.80 0.68 0.83 0.69
Province FE No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Social Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Development Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Robust standard errors in brackets, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Social controls include the population share of Christians, tribes, Buddhists and CRFI. Development controls include income taxes per-capita,
urbanization rate, a dummy for coastal districts, population share supported by commerce, population share supported by industry and
population share supported by professionals. The years of Muslim Rule coefficient is in terms of hundreds of years. See text for details.
40
TABLE 7B: DOES A LEGACY OF MUSLIM RULE AFFECT LITERACY?
LITERACY RATES POPULATION AGED 10 TO 20
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim
1911 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu -0.057 0.061* -0.657 0.103 -0.076 0.031 -0.771 0.02
[0.189] [0.036] [0.543] [0.122] [0.193] [0.049] [0.650] [0.112]
Fraction Muslim 0.034 -0.076 0.495 -0.431** -0.017 -0.094 0.367 -0.413**
[0.177] [0.052] [0.357] [0.173] [0.187] [0.078] [0.509] [0.189]
Fraction Hindu
2
0.629 -0.122 0.688 -0.068
[0.447] [0.141] [0.578] [0.130]
Fraction Muslim
2
-0.349 0.392** -0.302 0.332**
[0.424] [0.166] [0.573] [0.163]
Years of Muslim Rule -0.005*** -0.014*** -0.008*** -0.014*** 0.004 -0.014* 0.004 -0.014*
[0.002] [0.003] [0.002] [0.002] [0.005] [0.008] [0.005] [0.007]
Observations 200 193 200 193 200 193 200 193
Adj. R-squared 0.49 0.57 0.53 0.61 0.48 0.58 0.54 0.61
1921 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu 0.015 -0.008 -0.028 0.185 -0.028 0.001 -0.149 0.034
[0.070] [0.045] [0.120] [0.153] [0.078] [0.052] [0.120] [0.138]
Fraction Muslim 0.136* -0.183*** 0.004 -0.824*** 0.032 -0.150* -0.243 -0.500**
[0.079] [0.062] [0.170] [0.222] [0.088] [0.078] [0.169] [0.214]
Fraction Hindu
2
0.004 -0.331* 0.035 -0.116
[0.125] [0.175] [0.123] [0.160]
Fraction Muslim
2
0.152 0.636*** 0.291** 0.343*
[0.129] [0.202] [0.133] [0.188]
Years of Muslim Rule -0.009*** -0.019*** -0.010*** -0.018*** 0.008* -0.021** 0.008* -0.021**
[0.002] [0.003] [0.002] [0.003] [0.005] [0.009] [0.005] [0.009]
Observations 200 197 200 197 200 197 200 197
Adj. R-squared 0.74 0.57 0.75 0.61 0.76 0.63 0.79 0.65
Province FE No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Social Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Development Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Robust standard errors in brackets, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Social controls include the population share of Christians, tribes, Buddhists and CRFI. Development controls include income taxes per-capita,
urbanization rate, a dummy for coastal districts, population share supported by commerce, population share supported by industry and
population share supported by professionals. The years of Muslim Rule coefficient is in terms of hundreds of years. See text for details.
41
TABLE 7C: DOES A LEGACY OF MUSLIM RULE AFFECT LITERACY?
MALE AND FEMALE LITERACY
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Male Female
Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim Hindu Muslim
1911 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu 0.239** 0.088 0.253* 0.046 -0.402 -0.01 -1.731 -0.02
[0.104] [0.067] [0.141] [0.163] [0.438] [0.007] [1.482] [0.019]
Fraction Muslim 0.278** -0.098 -0.437** -0.488** -0.35 -0.038*** 1.266 -0.067***
[0.121] [0.102] [0.197] [0.247] [0.416] [0.010] [1.123] [0.024]
Fraction Hindu
2
-0.187 -0.058 1.533 0.001
[0.136] [0.184] [1.308] [0.020]
Fraction Muslim
2
0.731*** 0.410* -1.48 0.032
[0.160] [0.225] [1.295] [0.023]
Years of Muslim Rule 0.008 -0.026** 0.008 -0.026** 0.002 0 0.001 0
[0.007] [0.011] [0.006] [0.010] [0.004] [0.001] [0.006] [0.001]
Observations 200 193 200 193 200 193 200 193
Adj. R-squared 0.77 0.65 0.82 0.67 0.01 0.52 0.08 0.54
1921 CROSS-SECTION
Fraction Hindu 0.052 0.05 0.03 0.046 -0.006 -0.027* -0.066 -0.006
[0.094] [0.067] [0.132] [0.167] [0.017] [0.015] [0.042] [0.036]
Fraction Muslim 0.096 -0.188* -0.449** -0.635** 0.021 -0.070*** 0.024 -0.127**
[0.108] [0.096] [0.194] [0.268] [0.020] [0.024] [0.059] [0.054]
Fraction Hindu
2
-0.119 -0.109 0.053 -0.032
[0.138] [0.193] [0.046] [0.041]
Fraction Muslim
2
0.547*** 0.445* 0.006 0.054
[0.156] [0.242] [0.049] [0.045]
Years of Muslim Rule 0.009 -0.030** 0.009 -0.030*** 0.002 -0.002 0.002 -0.002
[0.007] [0.011] [0.006] [0.011] [0.002] [0.002] [0.002] [0.002]
Observations 200 197 200 197 200 197 200 197
Adj. R-squared 0.78 0.68 0.82 0.69 0.60 0.54 0.62 0.54
Province FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Social Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Development Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Robust standard errors in brackets, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Social controls include the population share of Christians, tribes, Buddhists and CRFI. Development controls include income taxes per-capita,
urbanization rate, a dummy for coastal districts, population share supported by commerce, population share supported by industry and
population share supported by professionals. The years of Muslim Rule coefficient is in terms of hundreds of years. See text for details.