OURS TO HACK AND TO OWN
OURS
TO HACK
AND TO OWN
THE RISE OF PLATFORM COOPERATIVISM,
A NEW VISION FOR THE FUTURE OF WORK
AND A FAIRER INTERNET
OURS
TO HACK
AND TO OWN
THE RISE OF PLATFORM COOPERATIVISM,
A NEW VISION FOR THE FUTURE OF WORK
AND A FAIRER INTERNET
EDITED BY
TREBOR SCHOLZ
AND NATHAN SCHNEIDER
OR Books
New York • London
Anthology selection © 2016 Trebor Scholz and Nathan Schneider.
The following authors have placed their contributions under a Creative
Commons Attribution-ShareAlike 4.0 International license: Michel Bauwens
and Vasilis Kostakis, Yochai Benkler, Francesca Bria, Miriam A. Cherry, Ra
Criscitiello, Max Dana, Joshua Danielson, Joel Dietz, John Duda, Enric Duran,
Matan Field, Noemi Giszpenc, Mayo Fuster Morell, Marina Gorbis, Jessica
Gordon Nembhard, Seda Gürses, Peter Harris, Steven Hill, Pedro Jardim,
Francis Jervis, Mary Jo Kaplan, Dmytri Kleiner, Brendan Martin, Rachel
O’Dwyer, Rory Ridley-Du, Carmen Rojas, Douglas Rushko, Nathan
Schneider, Trebor Scholz, Juliet B. Schor, Kati Sipp, Tom Slee, Christoph Spehr,
Danny Spitzberg, Armin Steuernagel, Arun Sundararajan, Ashley Taylor, Astra
Taylor, Cameron Tonkinwise, Akseli Virtanen, McKenzie Wark, Felix Weth,
Brianna Wettlaufer, Chad Whitacre, Aaron Wolf, and Caroline Woolard.
All individual contributions to this anthology © the respective author of the
contribution.
Published by OR Books, New York and London
Visit our website at www.orbooks.com
All rights information: rights@orbooks.com
All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced or transmitted in any
form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopy, recording,
or any information storage retrieval system, without permission in writing from
the publisher, except brief passages for review purposes.
First printing 2016
Cataloging-in-Publication data is available from the Library of Congress.
A catalog record for this book is available from the British Library.
ISBN 978-1-68219-062-3 paperback
ISBN 978-1-68219-063-0 e-book
Text design by Under|Over. Typeset by AarkMany Media, Chennai, India.
Printed by BookMobile in the United States and CPI Books Ltd in the United
Kingdom.
TABLE OF CONTENTS
PART 1 SOMETHING TO SAY YES TO
1. Trebor Scholz and Nathan Schneider - What This Is
and Isn’t About
2. Nathan Schneider - The Meanings of Words
3. Trebor Scholz - How Platform Cooperativism Can
Unleash the Network
4. Susie Cagle - The Seven Cooperative Principles
5. Jessica Gordon Nembhard - Eight Facts about
Cooperative Enterprise
PART 2 PLATFORM CAPITALISM
6. Douglas Rushko - Renaissance Now
7. Juliet B. Schor - Old Exclusion in Emergent Spaces
8. McKenzie Wark - Worse Than Capitalism
9. Steven Hill - How the Un-Sharing Economy
Threatens Workers
10. Christoph Spehr - SpongeBob, Why Dont You Work
Harder?
11. Kati Sipp - Portable Reputation in the On-Demand
Economy
12. Dmytri Kleiner - Counterantidisintermediation
13. David Bollier - From Open Access to Digital Commons
PART 3 AN INTERNET OF OUR OWN
Showcase 1 - Platforms
Stocksy United
Fairmondo
Coopify
Gratipay
FairCoop
9
11
14
20
27
29
31
33
38
43
48
54
59
63
69
75
77
78
79
80
81
82
Member’s Media, Ltd. Cooperative
TimesFree
Snowdrift.coop
Resonate
Loconomics Cooperative
NYC Real Estate Investment Cooperative
Robin Hood Collective
Seed.Coop
14. Yochai Benkler - The Realism of Cooperativism
15. Janelle Orsi - Three Essential Building Blocks for
Your Platform Cooperative
16. Caroline Woolard - So You Want to Start a Platform
Cooperative
17. Melissa Hoover - What We Mean When We Say
“Cooperative”
18. David Carroll - A Dierent Kind of Startup Is Possible
19. Marina Gorbis - Designing Positive Platforms
20. Cameron Tonkinwise - Convenient Solidarity:
Designing for Platform Cooperativism
21. Seda Gürses - Designing for Privacy
22. Danny Spitzberg - How Crowdfunding Becomes
Stewardship
23. Arun Sundararajan - Economic Barriers and Enablers
of Distributed Ownership
24. Ra Criscitiello - There Is Platform-Power in a Union
25. Saskia Sassen - Making Apps for Low-Wage Workers
and Their Neighborhoods
26. Kristy Milland - The Crowd: Naturally Cooperative,
Unnaturally Silenced
27. Tom Slee - Platforms and Trust: Beyond Reputation
Systems
28. Michel Bauwens and Vasilis Kostakis - Why Platform
Co-ops Should Be Open Co-ops
83
84
85
86
87
88
89
90
91
96
102
108
113
119
125
130
135
140
145
149
154
158
163
PART 4 CONDITIONS OF POSSIBILITY
Showcase 2 - Ecosystem
Loomio Cooperative Ltd.
The FairShares Model
Swarm Alliance
Ms., The Madeline System
Purpose Fund
rCredits
External Revenue Service
Data Commons Cooperative
Coliga
CommunityOS: Callicoon Project
Backfeed
My User Agreement
29. John Duda - Beyond Luxury Cooperativism
30. Brendan Martin - Money Is the Root of All Platforms
31. Carmen Rojas - From People-Centered Ideas to
People-Powered Capital
32. Karen Gregory - Can Code Schools Go Cooperative?
33. Palak Shah - A Code for Good Work
34. Micky Metts - Meet Your Friendly Neighborhood
Tech Co-op
35. Michael Peck - Building the People’s Ownership
Economy through Union Co-ops
36. Mayo Fuster Morell - Toward a Theory of Value for
Platform Cooperatives
37. Francesca Bria - Public Policies for Digital Sovereignty
38. Miriam A. Cherry - Legal and Governance Structures
Built to Share
39. Rachel O’Dwyer - Blockchains and Their Pitfalls
40. Astra Taylor - Non-Cooperativism
Contributors
Acknowledgments
Further Resources
167
169
170
171
172
173
174
175
176
177
178
179
180
181
182
187
192
196
200
204
208
213
218
223
228
233
239
249
251
PART 1
SOMETHING TO SAY
YES TO
11
1. WHAT THIS IS AND ISN’T
ABOUT
TREBOR SCHOLZ AND NATHAN SCHNEIDER
This is a guidebook for a fairer kind of Internet. While we intend to
foster something new in the online economy, we do so by turning to
something old: the long tradition of cooperative enterprise. The prob-
lems of labor abuse and surveillance that have arisen with the “sharing
economy,” also, are not entirely new; they have much in common with
struggles on nineteenth-century factory oors. By considering the
emerging platforms in light of well-hewn cooperative principles and
practices, we nd an optimistic vision for the future of work and life.
Already, this strategy is catching on. Workers, organizers, devel-
opers, and social entrepreneurs around the world are experimenting
with cooperative platforms and forming conversations about platform
cooperativism. This book, therefore, is an eort to serve a movement
in the making, to add to the momentum we and our fellow contribu-
tors already feel.
We each came to platform cooperativism by somewhat separate
paths. Trebor had been convening the Digital Labor conferences at
The New School since 2009, from which arose an earlier book, The
Internet as Playground and Factory. In publications like The Nation and
Vice, Nathan was reporting on the protest movements of 2011 and
eorts among young people to create ethical livelihoods, online and
o, once the protests receded. We met at OuiShare Fest in Paris in
2014, and, at Trebor’s “Sweatshops, Picket Lines, and Barricades” con-
ference later the same year, we both sensed it was time to think about
constructive alternatives to the dominant Silicon Valley model.
12
That December, Trebor published “Platform Cooperativism vs. the
Sharing Economy,” framing this concept that would come to be this
movement’s moniker. The same month, Shareable published Nathans
article “Owning Is the New Sharing,” which mapped out some of the
eorts to build cooperative platforms already underway. Realizing
our common interest, we discussed these ideas with interested plat-
form-workers, labor advocates, techies, and luddites—many of whom,
we found, were venturing into various forms of platform cooperativism
already. We agreed it was time that they should meet each other.
In November 2015, we held a two-day event called “Platform
Cooperativism: The Internet, Ownership, Democracy” at The New
School. More than a thousand people came, including New York City
Council members, CEOs, investors, platform creators, and leading
scholars. The Washington Post deemed the event “a huge success.
Shortly after, the Rosa Luxemburg Foundation published Trebor’s
primer on platform cooperativism, which has been translated into at
least seven languages. Follow-up events have taken place in Barcelona,
Berlin, Bologna, Boulder, London, Melbourne, Paris, Rome, Milan,
Vancouver, and elsewhere.
Before we get started, let’s make sure we are talking about the
same thing: shared governance and shared ownership of the Internet’s
levers of power—its platforms and protocols. Democratic ownership
and governance are the pillars of what cooperativism refers to, both here
and historically; without these, the word rings hollow.
Second, this book calls for a process, not another trick of tech-
nological solutionism. Platform cooperativism will not come about
simply through a few killer apps; it will require a dierent kind of eco-
system—with appropriate forms of nance, law, policy, and culture
to support the development of democratic online enterprises. This
means challenging the cooperative movement to meet the opportuni-
ties of the platform economy, and challenging the platform economy
to overcome its obsession with short-term prots for the few.
Platform cooperativism is a radical horizon, to be sure, but
we should not regard it as an absolute. There will be multiple and
13
sometimes partial means of getting there. A company that shares some
ownership and governance is better than one that shares none, and we
celebrate that. We encourage a variety of strategies and experiments.
The contributors to this book, in that spirit, represent diverse
approaches and perspectives. It is a means of sharing what we learned
from the 2015 Platform Cooperativism event more widely, and of
drawing more people into the work of overcoming the challenges we
face. We can keep the conversation going at platformcoop.net, a place
for ongoing discussion of news, resources, and ideas.
After these introductory chapters, the rst set of essays considers
the opportunities and challenges of the existing online economy,
demonstrating the need for more cooperative approaches. The second
section addresses the practical design and development of coopera-
tive online platforms; it includes “showcases” of actually existing and
in-development platform co-ops. In the third section, we step back to
consider the broader ecosystems that well need to develop if we are
serious about making shared ownership and governance a new norm
for the Internet; here, too, are showcases that show how far the plat-
form co-op ecosystem has already come.
Throughout this process, we have been amazed by the enthusiasm
and experience that so many people around the world have brought to
the #platformcoop conversation, and the eort to make it a reality. We
hope this book does justice to the power of what is already underway,
as well as the hurdles we still face together. We dedicate the book to
those with the courage and imagination to create an Internet worthy
of the people it connects.
14
2. THE MEANINGS OF WORDS
NATHAN SCHNEIDER
For most of the last decade, I’ve been a reporter, covering stories on
how technology is reshaping public life, from debates about God
to protests in the streets. One thing I’ve noticed is that Internet
culture has an odd way of using a really important word: democracy.
When a new app is said to be democratizing something—whether
robotic personal assistants or sepia-toned seles—it means allowing
more people to access that something. Just access, along with a big,
fat terms of service. Gone are those old associations of town meet-
ings and voting booths; gone are co-ownership, co-governance, and
accountability.
Words are the tools of my trade as a writer, so I like to have a
handle on what they mean. We rely on them so much. They connect
us to each other; they remind us what were capable of. And I hope
that the Internet can help us make our denitions of democracy more
ambitious, rather than redening it out of existence.
In late 2014 I was reporting a story about Amazons Mechanical
Turk platform, a website where users can nd entirely online piece-
workjobs that might take between seconds and hours, like tran-
scribing a receipt, providing feedback on an ad, or taking a sociological
survey. I went to Trebor Scholz’s Digital Labor conference in New
York, which included real-life Mechanical Turkers. One was a wife
whose husband lost his job, for instance; another was a former cable
technician. I heard them describing what working on the platform is
like. Employers can review them, but they can’t review employers.
Their work can be rejected with no remuneration or recourse. There
15
are no constraints to prevent below-minimum-wage pay. One of them
complained in the media and her account was frozen.
Over the course of those days, a kind of question kept coming
up among the Turkers, a thought experiment. They wondered aloud:
What if we owned the platform? How would we set the rules?
They’d sit with that for a minute or two, batting ideas back and
forth about how to make the platform better for themselves—and for
Amazon. Reasonable ideas. Clever ones. But then the ideas would fade
back into reality again: back to the complaints.
Since then the agonies over the dictionary-altering Internet have
only intensied. People have blockaded Google Buses to protest
wealth inequality in San Francisco, and Uber drivers have gone on
strike around the world. Increasingly this online economy is becoming
the economy—the way more and more of us nd jobs, relationships,
and a roof over our heads. Internet companies aspire to network and
monetize everything from our cars to our refrigerators; the companies
call this the “Internet of things.” But the Turkers’ questions have kept
coming back to me.
Were they on to something? What if the platforms and networks
really were ours? What if we had an Internet of ownership?
REAL SHARING, REAL DEMOCRACY
Another word that the Internet has gotten to is sharing. Sharing used
to mean something we do with the people we know and trust. In the
so-called sharing economy, it means more convenient transactions that
take place on distant servers somewhere. Convenience is great, but all
along there has been a real sharing economy at work, the cooperative
economy.
One can trace the modern cooperative movement to the Rochdale
Principles of 1844, in England, though it had precursors among ancient
tribes, monasteries, and guilds around the world. The rudiments of this
stu could be basic common sense: shared ownership and governance
16
among people who depend on an enterprise, shared prots, and coor-
dination among enterprises rather than competition.
We might not know it, but co-ops are all around us. In Colorado,
where I live, 70 percent of the state’s territory gets its power from coop-
erative electric companies that date to the 1930s and earlier, owned
and governed by the people they serve. The credit union where I’m
a member is one of the top mortgage lenders in the region. Up in the
mountains west of me, some years back, a group of neighbors started
their own co-op Internet service provider. There’s also Land O’Lakes,
Organic Valley, and REI.
Co-ops come in all shapes and sizes. They fail less than other
businesses, and they often pay better wages (except to top executives).
Democracy, it turns out, worksthough it can be less lucrative for
those just trying to get rich. People in charge are harder to swindle.
I lived in a co-op house once; it followed a certain dirty, organic,
folk-music-every-night stereotype. The same couldn’t be said, though,
for what I saw at Kenya’s business school for managers of cooperatives.
There, co-ops hold about half the GDP, and those students looked
like business students anywhereexcept that, along with all the mar-
keting and case studies, they were also learning how to run a company
where the people who work for you are your bosses. In the area around
Barcelona, among the thousands of members of the Catalan Integral
Cooperative, I got a glimpse of what twenty-rst-century coopera-
tives might look like. Rather than securing old-fashioned jobs, these
independent workers help each other become less dependent on sala-
ries, and more able to rely on the housing, food, childcare, and com-
puter code they hold in common. They trade with their own digital
currency. In cases like this, the traditional lines between workers, pro-
ducers, consumers, and depositors may become harder to draw.
Part of the cooperative legacy has played out in tech culture
already. The Internet relies on free, open-source tools built through
feats of peer-to-peer self-governance, like Wikipedia and Linux. Visit
many tech oces, from a startup’s garage to the Googleplex, and there
are self-organizing teams creating projects from the bottom up. Yet
17
somehow this democracy doesn’t seem to make it to the boardroom;
things are still pretty twentieth-century corporate in there, with who-
ever happens to own the most shares calling the shots. There’s a re-
wall. We can practice democracy everywhere, it seems, except where
it really matters.
There are some pretty sci- questions before us these days: Will
apps and robots replace our jobs? Will any aspect of our digital lives
escape the notice of surveillance? Can there be a digital utopia without
the dystopias of sweatshops and blood minerals? In each case the coop-
erative tradition poses necessary questions, which in the onrush of
change we may neglect to ask: Who owns the tools we live by, and
how are they governed?
PLATFORM COMMONS
Cooperative enterprises of the past and present have relied on two
kinds of strategies to gain a foothold in economies and cultures prem-
ised on competition. One is the competitive advantage to be found
in cooperation—the ability to succeed where conventional markets
fail, for instance, and the power latent in solidarity. The second is
when the rules of the system are changed to support more coopera-
tive practices—especially through governments that see the value of
cooperative enterprise enough to encourage and fund it. For platform
cooperativism to ourish, I suspect we need both of these.
We can begin by identifying the competitive advantages of coop-
eration. Cooperative practices, for instance, are poised to thicken the
notoriously loose ties that online connectedness normally oers. And
as big tech companies continue having diculty treating workers and
users as—well, peopleco-ops can oer positive, ethical alternatives
that workers and users can turn to. Hybrid modelscombining aspects
of a conventional company with aspects of cooperative ownership and
governanceseem promising in the short term. Yet the rules of the
system remain very much tilted against cooperativism.
18
This needs to change. Governments should recognize that coop-
erative platforms will mean more wealth staying in their communities
and serving their constituents. Rather than trying (and failing) to say
“no” to the likes of Uber, platform co-ops are something public insti-
tutions can say “yes” to. We need laws that make it easier to form and
nance co-ops, as well as public investment in business development—
stu that extractive businesses get all the time.
This also means thinking dierently about the incumbents. The
Facebooks, Googles, and Ubers aren’t just regular companies anymore.
Their business models are based on how dependent so many of us are
on them; their ubiquity, in turn, is what makes them useful. They’re
becoming public utilities. The less we have a choice about whether to
use them, the more we need democracy to step in. What if a new gen-
eration of antitrust laws, instead of breaking up the emerging online
utilities, created a pathway to more democratic ownership?
Rather than donating Facebook shares to his own LLC, Mark
Zuckerberg could put them into a trust owned and controlled by
Facebook users themselves. Then they, too, could have a seat in the
boardroom when decisions are made about what to do with all that
valuable personal data they pour into the platform—and they’d have a
stake in ensuring the platform succeeds. How would you vote?
These aren’t just questions about what kind of Internet we want,
or even what kind of world we want; they’re about how we see our-
selves. Do we trust ourselves enough to expect democracy from the
institutions on which we rely? Are we bold enough to imagine, as the
Mechanical Turkers were, what the Internet would look like if we
were in charge?
Thirty years ago, when the Internet wasn’t much more than a
lab experiment, the social critic Theodore Roszak saw a lot of this
coming. “Making the democratic most of the Information Age,” he
wrote in The Cult of Information, “is a matter not only of technology
but also of the social organization of that technology.
We forget that. New gizmos come and go so quickly that we hardly
notice when the meanings of our words change, and when what we
19
expect of ourselves changes with them. Ordinary people have already
made the Internet their own with their hacks, their memes, their pro-
tests, and their dreams. The cost of forfeiting control over these things
is too high, and too mysterious. We need to expect better, to demand
more. It’s time that we own and govern what is ours already.
20
3. HOW PLATFORM
COOPERATIVISM CAN
UNLEASH THE NETWORK
TREBOR SCHOLZ
In 1998 I moved into a small Buddhist temple in San Franciscos
Mission District. My spiritual comrades in this commune could not
understand why I would spend all the money that I had saved on an
IBM laptop when the community already owned a computer. As
someone who studies the social impact of the Internet, I was surprised
by the proposal to collectively use one computer. For me, up to that
point, thinking about the Internet meant thinking about individual
use, not communal ownership. This episode showed me how a cul-
ture of genuine sharing can also mean sharing technology, just like
anything else.
Over the past ve years, the technological ingenuity of the
“sharing economy” deeply resonated with the zeitgeist. Emphasizing
community, underutilized resources, and open data, the genuine
sharing economy was initially presented as a challenge to corporate
power. Just like my Buddhist friends, the pioneers of this economy
proposed to split the use of lawn mowers, drills, and cars. But soon,
the non-commercial values behind many platforms were rewritten in
the boardrooms of Silicon Valley, turning the “sharing economy” into
a misnomer. Today, facing various prophecies about sharing and the
future of work, we need to remind ourselves that there is no unstop-
pable evolution leading to the uberization of society; more positive
alternatives are possible.
21
In Average Is Over, the economist Tyler Cowen foresees a future in
which a tiny “hyper meritocracy” would make millions while the rest
of us struggle to survive on anywhere between $5,000 and $10,000
a year. It already works quite well in Mexico, Cowen quips. Carl B.
Frey and Michael A. Osborne predict that 47 percent of all jobs are
at risk of being automated over the next twenty years. And I have
no doubt about the vision of platform owners like Travis Kalanick
(Uber), Je Bezos (Amazon), or Lukas Biewald (CrowdFlower)—
who, in the absence of government regulation and resistance from
workers, will simply exploit their undervalued workers. I’m all on
board for Paul Mason’s and Kathi Weeks’ visions for a post-capitalist,
post-work future where universal basic income will rule the way we
think about life opportunities. In the United States, however, unlike
in Finland, the chances for this scenario becoming a reality over the
next two years are not high. The question then becomes what we can
do right now, with and for the most precarious among the contingent
third of the American workforce, which is unlikely to see the return
of the traditional safety net, the forty-hour workweek, or a steady
paycheck.
Today’s Internet bears little resemblance to the ARPA-designed,
non-commercial, decentralized, post-Sputnik network. We are
nding that the sources of our entertainment, the platforms where
we are logging on to work every day, and the apps that constantly
draw us into feedback loops are all owned by a small number of deep-
pocketed founders and stockholders. That’s simply unacceptable, and it
is for this reason that I proposed a theory of “platform cooperativism”
in 2014. Workers in the on-demand economy are called upon to “live
like lions,“ but with slightly more exibility have come more risks and
harsher taskmasters. The average on-demand economy worker earns
$7,900 a year through labor platforms, which indicates that many of
them work only part-time in this digital economy. Often disregarded
in this discussion are those who are pushed out of the market by, for
example, Uber drivers, who are 40 percent college-educated and more
likely to be white than legacy taxi drivers who may lose their jobs.
22
Many of the business models of the “sharing economy” are based
on the strategic nullication of the law. Companies knowingly vio-
late city regulations and labor laws. This allows them to undermine
the competition and then point to a large customer base to demand
legislative changes that benet their dubious modus operandi. Firms
are also activating their app-based consumers as a grassroots polit-
ical movement to help them lobby for corporate interests. Privacy
should be a concern for workers and customers, too. Uber is ana-
lyzing the routines of its customers, from their commutes to their
one-night stands, to then impose surge pricing when they most
rely on the service. Navigating legal gray zones, these deregulated
commerce hubs sometimes misclassify employees as independent
contractors. They are labeling them “turkers,” “driver-partners,
or “rabbits,” but never workers. Hiding behind the curtain of the
Internet, they would like us to believe that they are tech rather than
labor companies.
In the decade between 2000 and 2010, the median income in the
United States declined by 7 percent when adjusted for ination. In
2014 51 percent of Americans made less than $30,000 a year, and 76
percent of them had no savings whatsoever. Since the 1970s, we have
witnessed concerted eorts to move people out of direct employment,
which has led to the steady growth of the number of independent con-
tractors and freelancers. Digital labor, a child of the low-wage crisis, is
part of that process.
What has the “sharing economy” really gotten us? Beyond the
consumer convenience and eciency in creating short-term prots
for the few, it has demonstrated how, in terms of social well-being
and environmental sustainability, capitalism turns out to be amazingly
ineective in watching out for people. Seemingly overnight, the gains
of more than one hundred years of labor struggles, dating back to the
Haymarket Riots in 1886 and the protests after the Shirtwaist Factory
re in 1911, have been stalled. Also, the Fair Labor Standards Act of
1938 suddenly has far less pull because the number of employees is
shrinking rapidly.
23
Among all the problems of the twenty-rst century that are related
to workers—inequality, stagnant wages, loss of rights—the biggest
predicament is that there seem to be so few realistic alternatives. But
there are. I will identify four approaches.
The rst two approaches are based on the belief in negotiation
with corporate owners and with government. The Domestic Workers
Alliance, for example, formulated a Good Work Code in hopes that
policy makers would endorse their guidelines and that platform
owners would follow them. Seattle imposed a tax on Uber and gave
drivers the right to unionize, Mayor Bill de Blasio of New York City
made attempts to curb the number of Uber cars, and the city of San
Francisco tried to regulate Airbnb. A third pathway is to move pro-
duction outside of the market altogether. Yochai Benkler labeled this
“non-market peer production,” with the most successful example being
Wikipedia. And, nally, for the compensated labor market, there is a
fourth approach, which is platform cooperativism, a model of social
organization based on the understanding that it is hard to substantially
change what you don’t own.
My thinking about platform cooperativism owes much to the
Digital Labor conferences at The New School. These events started in
2009 and one of the recent ones was Platform Cooperativism in 2015.
Initially, at these events, discussions focused on the Italian Workerists,
immaterial labor, and “playbor.” Artists like Burak Arikan, Alex
Rivera, Stephanie Rothenberg, and Dmytri Kleiner played pioneering
roles in alerting the public to these issues. Later, debates became more
concerned with “crowd eecing,” the exploitation of thousands of
invisible workers in crowdsourcing systems like Amazon Mechanical
Turk or content moderation farms in the Philippines. Over the past
few years, the search for concrete alternatives for a better future of
work has become more dynamic.
The theory of platform cooperativism has two main tenets: com-
munal ownership and democratic governance. It is bringing together
135 years of worker self-management, the roughly 170 years of the
cooperative movement, and commons-based peer production with the
24
compensated digital economy. The term “platform” refers to places
where we hang out, work, tinker, and generate value after we switch on
our phones or computers. The “cooperativism” part is about an own-
ership model for labor and logistics platforms or online marketplaces
that replaces the likes of Uber with cooperatives, communities, cities,
or inventive unions. These new structures embrace the technology to
creatively reshape it, embed their values, and then operate it in sup-
port of local economies. Seriously, why does a village in Denmark
or a town like Marfa in rural West Texas have to generate prots for
some fty people in Silicon Valley if they can create their own version
of Airbnb? Instead of trying to be the next Silicon Valley, generating
prots for the few, these cities could mandate the use of a cooperative
platform, which could maximize use value for the community.
Platform co-ops already exist, from cooperatively owned online
labor brokerages and marketplaces like Fairmondo, to video streaming
sites that are owned by lmmakers and their fans. Photographers
co-own the stock photography cooperative Stocksy and massage
therapists in San Francisco started the freelancer-owned online labor
market Loconomics. Students at Cornell University built Coopify
for (and with) co-ops of low-income immigrants in Sunset Park,
Brooklyn. Platform co-ops could be attractive options for home health
care professionals and also low-income residents, or pensioners who
need to earn extra cash. In the United States, the 650,000 people who
are released from U.S. prisons every year would be likely to welcome
dignied work. And nally, platform co-ops might be attractive for
refugees, for whom it often takes as long as eight years after their
immigration to nd a job, even in a country like Sweden. With this
model, workers can become collective owners; they do no longer have
to subscribe to the pathology of the old system that trained them to be
followers.
Few people will feel drawn to build a platform co-op based on
abstract principles. But for the already committed, common principles
and values matter. From the Rochdale Society of Equitable Pioneers,
to African-American cooperatives in the South of the United States,
25
to the Mondragon Corporation in Spain, forming any kind of coop-
erative endeavor has always started with a study group. Political sci-
entist Elinor Ostrom reminded us that aspiring to create alternatives
without rigorous study is a pipe dream, a vain hope. Being realistic
about cooperative culture is essential. From the history of cooperatives
in the United States, we learned that they are indeed able to oer a
more stable income and a dignied workplace. While the necessary
enthusiasm of makers doesn’t always sit well with justiably skeptical
scholars, their dialogue is important. Jointly, they could rewrite the
Rochdale principles for the digital economy, for instance. Education is
an essential cornerstone of platform cooperativism.
Platform co-ops should consider the following principles. The
rst one, which I explained already, is communal ownership of plat-
forms and protocols. Second, platform co-ops have to be able to oer
income security and good pay for all people working for the co-op.
And history shows that co-ops are able to oer this. Emilia-Romagna,
an area in Italy that encouraged employee ownership, consumer coop-
eratives, and agricultural co-ops, has lower unemployment than other
regions in Italy. The agship of cooperatives, Mondragon, is a network
of co-ops that employed 74,061 people in 2013. But in the United
States, despite its dominance in areas like orange juice production, the
cooperative model has been faced with many challenges, including
competition with multinational corporate giants, public awareness,
self-exploitation, and the network eect. So, it is essential for platform
co-ops to study the communities they’d like to serve and get their
value proposition right.
In opposition to the black-box systems of the Snowden-era Internet,
these platforms need to distinguish themselves by making their data
ows transparent. They need to show where the data about customers
and workers are stored, to whom they are sold, and for what purpose.
Work on platform co-ops needs to be co-determined. The people who
are meant to populate the platform in the end must be involved in its
design from the very beginning. They need to understand the parameters
and patterns that govern their working environment. A protective legal
26
framework is not only essential to guarantee the right to organize and
the freedom of expression but it can help to guard against platform-based
child labor, wage theft, arbitrary behavior, litigation, and excessive work-
place surveillance along the lines of the “reputation systems” of companies
like Lyft and Uber that “deactivate” drivers if their ratings fall below 4.5
stars. Crowd workers should have a right to know what they are working
on instead of contributing to mysterious projects posted by anonymous
consignors.
At its heart, platform cooperativism is not about any particular
technology but the politics of lived acts of cooperation. Soon, we may
no longer have to contend with websites and apps but, more and more,
with 5G wireless services (more mobile work), protocols, and AI. We
have to design for tomorrow’s labor market. In the absence of rigorous
democratic debates, online labor behemoths are producing their ver-
sion of the future of work right in front of us. We have to move quickly.
Together with cities like Berlin, Barcelona, Paris, and Rio de Janeiro,
which have already pushed back against Uber and Airbnb, we ought to
rene the discourse around “smart cities” and machine ownership. We
need incubators, small experiments, step-by-step walkthroughs, best
practices, and legal templates that online co-ops can use. Developers
will script a WordPress for platform co-ops, a free-software labor
platform that local developers can customize. Ultimately, platform
cooperativism is not merely about countering destructive visions of
the future, it is about the marriage of technology and cooperativism
and what it can do for our children, our children’s children, and their
children into the future.
27
28
29
5. EIGHT FACTS ABOUT
COOPERATIVE ENTERPRISE
JESSICA GORDON NEMBHARD
1. Cooperative enterprises address market failure and need.
They provide rural electricity or other utilities in sparsely popu-
lated areas; aordable healthy and organic foods, especially in food
deserts; access to credit and banking services; access to aordable
housing; access to quality aordable child or elder care; and access
to markets for culturally sensitive goods and arts.
2. Cooperatives overcome historical barriers to development
in the ways they aggregate people, resources, and capital. Of 162
non-agricultural cooperatives in one study, 44 percent of the
respondents said they could not have opened their business had it
not been organized as a cooperative.
3. The economic activity of the approximately thirty thousand
cooperatives in the United States contributes an estimated
$154 billion to the nation’s total income. Co-ops have helped to
create over 2.1 million jobs, with an impact on wages and salaries of
almost $75 billion. After becoming owners of a house-cleaning co-op
in Oakland, the workers experienced a median income increase from
$24,000 to over $40,000.
4. Cooperative businesses have lower failure rates than other
businesses, both after the rst year (10 percent failure versus
60-80 percent) and after ve years (90 percent still operating
versus 3-5 percent). Evidence also shows that cooperatives suc-
cessfully address the eects of economic crises and survive crises
better.
30
5. Cooperatives are more likely to promote community
growth than an investor-oriented rm, since most are owned
and controlled by local residents. Since cooperative business
objectives are needs-oriented, cooperatives are more likely to
stay in the communities where they originate. For every $1,000
spent at a food co-op, $1,606 goes to the local economy; for every
$1 million in sales, 9.3 jobs are created.
6. Cooperative businesses stabilize communities because they
serve as business anchors, distributing, recycling, and multiplying
local expertise and capital. They enable their owners to generate
income and jobs; accumulate assets; provide aordable, quality
goods and services; and develop human and social capital.
7. Co-ops and their members pay taxes and are good
citizens. They tend to give donations to their communities, pay
their employees fairly, and use sustainable business practices.
8. Cooperative start-up costs can be low. Members can con-
tribute time and capital, osetting costs that require other busi-
nesses to seek outside nancing. Co-ops are also eligible to apply
for loans and grants from a number of federal and state agencies
designed to support co-op development, and are often provided
relatively low-cost loans from non-governmental nancial insti-
tutions like cooperative banks.
Adapted from Benets and Impacts of Cooperatives, working white paper
for the Center on Race and Wealth, Howard University (February 2014),
http://is.gd/ItoPHT.
PART 2
PLATFORM
CAPITALISM
33
6. RENAISSANCE NOW
DOUGLAS RUSHKOFF
What would it take to make the digital economy less like industrial
capitalism on steroids, and more consonant with the distributive nature
of digital networks themselves? People are trying a lot of strategies,
from peer-to-peer value exchanges and the restoration of the com-
mons to crowd-funded debt remediation schemes and local favor-banks.
Something big is going on here.
Surprisingly, perhaps, these eorts rarely involve digital technology
itself at their core. Rather, they are informed by a digital sensibility.
It turns out that we dont actually need blockchains to reconcile and
administrate the contributions that each driver has made to a driver-
owned version of Uber any more than we need cryptography to stage
a debt strike.
Such activities are not so much digital in their implementation as
they are in the hands-on, hacker ethos from which they emerge. Digital,
after all, refers rst and foremost to the ngers—the digits—through
which human beings create value. In a sense, the digital hearkens back
in time, not just ahead, to a time when people were not disconnected
from the value they created, and when the world was not simply a set
of resources to be extracted by corporations.
One wouldn’t know that from looking at the dominant players in
the digital economy today. Instead of remaking the economy from the
ground up, these companies—Amazon, Uber, Facebook, Apple…take
your pick—simply practice capitalism with digital tools. Their founders
are happy to “disrupt” one industry or another, but they never even
consider disrupting the landscape on which they are functioning—the
34
operating system of venture capital beneath all the apps and devices
they make.
As soon as a developer comes up with a potentially useful digital
technology, he (yes, usually a he) runs to a venture capitalist or invest-
ment banker for funds. Those funders then run the show. Satised
with nothing less than 100x returns on their money, they push the
founders to “pivot” the business toward outlandish, “home run” out-
comes. The object of the game is not to create a successful business,
but to “exit” through an IPO or acquisition before the business fails.
In spite of their abuse of the environmentalist’s lexicon, they do not
create sustainable “ecosystems” at all, but scorched-earth monopolies
through which no one—no onegets to create or exchange value.
That doesnt really matter. All they have to do is extract enough
value from people and places in order to sell themselves to someone
elseor leverage their monopoly in one market (like books or taxis)
to another one (like movies or robotic vehicles).
Looked at from a digital perspective, these companies are really
just software, optimized to extract as much value as they can from the
real world, and convert it into share price for their investors. They
take real, working, circulating currency, and turn it into frozen, static,
useless capital. That’s the digitally enabled division of wealth, in a nut-
shell. It’s not truly digital; it’s not hands-on, connective, or a hack of
the underlying operating system. It’s the same old industrialism, being
practiced with powerful new digital tools. It’s also utterly inconsistent
with the underlying biases of digital technology. That’s why such
schemes tend to work against the interests of real people or communi-
ties, and are bound to fail in the long run.
Industrialism, an outcome of the Renaissance, worked pretty well
as long as the economy was growing. Based on the premise of debt-
based central currency—interest-bearing bank notes—the object of
industrialism was to grow the economy so that more money could be
paid back to lenders than was borrowed.
Industrialism replaced the peer-to-peer economy of the late
Middle Ages. Skilled workers were shunned in favor of low-cost
35
assembly line laborers. Local currencies that promoted friction-
less exchange were replaced by high-cost, interest-bearing money.
Human connections between interdependent producers and service
providers were overtaken by articial connections between brands and
consumers. Acquisition became a human value more important than
pleasure itself, as we all (with a bit of help from marketing psycholo-
gists) took on the characteristics of competitive businesses in our daily
lives and interactions. America became a Tupperware party.
All this was engineered simply to extract value from the periphery
to the middle—from the real and ground-up to the abstract stocks and
bonds of the already wealthy. All in accordance with the underlying
biases of the Renaissance: the centralization of power, the rise of the
individual, the emergence of the chartered monopoly, and the spread
of empires to new continents. People and places were just slaves and
territories.
The dominant digital economy—the one driven by venture cap-
ital, the stock market, and business as usual—expresses these values
and exacerbates all the same mechanisms, treating people and places
the very same way that Renaissance princes did. Algorithms exacer-
bate the extractive nature of our markets, while companies like Uber
and Airbnb leverage monopolies to disempower labor and neighbor-
hoods. Where territorial expansion once supplied corporations with
new room for growth, in the digital age the only new surface area is
human time, awareness, and data. People spend an increasing amount
of their lives in service of a digital economy that delivers them nothing
in return. Meanwhile, the best minds out of MIT and Stanford are
hired to optimize every device, app, and operating system to do this
more completely.
Of course, those left jobless (or simply incapable of generating
income through the same work they’ve always done for pay) are among
the rst to challenge the underlying assumptions of the rst, faux dig-
ital economy. To them—to us—the digital age is still the harbinger of
something dierent than business as usual. It oers not a mere ampli-
cation of the worst of capitalism, but the possibility for a state change:
36
something as dierent from corporate industrialism as corporate indus-
trialism was from the artisanal marketplace of the late Middle Ages.
Indeed, just as the Renaissance retrieved the values of empire from
ancient Rome, and re-birthed them as capitalism and industrialism,
might the digital era constitute a renaissance of its own? And if it does,
what values will it retrieve?
Well, if history is any lesson, todays renaissance will retrieve
the values that were submerged and repressed by the last one. The
Renaissance obsolesced medieval attention to craft, quality, and per-
sonal connections among participants in the marketplace. Not only
were peer-to-peer currencies outlawed, but guilds were disbanded, the
commons were privatized, and craftspeople used to being paid for the
value they created became wage laborers working by the hour, with no
ownership stake in their enterprises.
Laugh all you like at the rise of artisanal beers and hand-knitted
sweaters, but these seemingly precious throwbacks augur the retrieval
of the medieval sensibility as surely as Burning Man, Game of Thrones,
and the newly expanded menu of body modications oered by the
piercing place at the mall. We are already retrieving the lost spirit of
medievalism in our culture and media.
The migration of this sensibility to our economy is next. And
necessary. Through the establishment of guilds, such as the Institute
of Electrical and Electronics Engineers, technologists are setting their
own standards for how they’ll apply their skillsand the price of the
NASDAQ is not on their list. Etsy retrieves the spirit of the peer-to-
peer marketplace, while the Creative Commons begins to compensate
for the privatization of shared intellectual resources.
Online favor-banks, time dollars, and local currencies retrieve the
possibility for direct, peer-to-peer exchange of value, while the block-
chain obsolesces the monopoly of central authorities over accounta-
bility and authentication.
Platform cooperatives—as a direct aront to the platform monop-
olies characterizing digital industrialism—oer a means of both
reclaiming the value we create and forging the solidarity we need
37
to work toward our collective good. Instead of extracting value and
delivering it up to distant shareholders, we harvest, circulate, and
recycle the value again and again. And those are precisely the habits we
must retrieve as we move ahead from an extractive and growth-based
economy to one as regenerative and sustainable as were going to need
to survive the great challenges of our time.
As the essays in this book make clear, the renaissance is on. Digital
is not simply a new high-tech tool to promote the agenda of the last
renaissance. It’s a good old human sensibility for bringing on the
next one.
38
7. OLD EXCLUSION IN
EMERGENT SPACES
JULIET B. SCHOR
It has been widely assumed by those drawn to the idea of platform cooper-
ativism that such platforms would help enhance gender and race diversity
and reduce the inequality that has often prevailed in the online economy
so far. But what evidence do we have that this would be the case?
For the last ve years, along with a team of PhD graduate students
in sociology, I have been studying platforms. We have been generously
funded by the MacArthur Foundation, which is interested in how dig-
ital technologies are aecting social life, opportunity, participation,
and social inequality. The research has mainly been qualitative: based
on interviews with people who engage in online platforms, or what
we have called the “connected economy,” as well as intensive ethno-
graphic research at connected economy sites. We started by concen-
trating on nonprot grassroots initiatives that were trying to re-shape
the way Americans get access to, exchange, and consume goods and
services, such as a time bank and a food swap. We later added educa-
tional and learning sites, such as online courses and workshops that
oer “upskilling,” and a makerspace. Then we moved on to the far
more controversial for-prots, such as Airbnb, and peer-to-peer car
rental sites. We’ve also been studying on-demand labor sites, including
TaskRabbit, Postmates, and Favor.
We’re interested in many aspects of these innovative arrange-
ments. How are they organized? Who is beneting from them? How
do people (on both sides of the markets) feel about them? What are the
dynamics of inequality and access that operate in these spaces?
39
Participants in the platform cooperativism movement have high
ambitions to create platforms that are owned and governed by their
users, that embody principles of equality and access, and that serve the
common good. They hope to develop “community” among partic-
ipants and to engage people in the maintenance of this community.
These are aspirations that are also shared by many of the innovators
and members of a number of the nonprot sites that we have studied.
There may be some shared challenges as well.
Consider three of our sites: the time bank, the food swap, and the
makerspace. The time bank is a volunteer-run and -led organization
that allows people to trade labor services on a purely egalitarian basis.
All types of services are welcome, so long as they are legal, and the
time bank has a wide diversity of oerings. They are all valued in
terms of the time it takes to provide them, irrespective of the market
value of the service; an hour of a lawyer or a plumber’s time is valued
at the same rate as that of a dog walker or someone oering a ride to
the airport. Similarly, in the food swap, people prepare foods in bulk
and bring them to trade with others’ preparations. There is no cost to
participate. Here, also, everyone’s food is valued more or less equally,
whatever its cost in terms of materials or labor; foods can be exchanged
at a one-to-one ratio for a roughly equivalent size. Our third site, the
makerspace, is also a place that attempts to create an open, accessible
site for people to learn to use a group of collectively owned tools, and
to become creative “makers.” The site oers classes and membership,
as well as a lively community of highly engaged individuals.
One of the central questions of our research is to assess the extent
to which the aspirations and ambitions of these sites are being real-
ized. Does an egalitarian trading economy work? Can it be expanded
to cover more services, more people, and more consumption needs?
Does the makerspace succeed at teaching skills and expanding its
community?
While there are many successes among our three sites, our research
also led to a troubling nding: all three cases are plagued with status-
seeking, subtle forms of social exclusion, and non-egalitarian behavior
40
that threatened the core goals of founders and members. They are also
all highly racialized sites in which nearly all participants are white. And
they are characterized by gender skews as well. The time bank and food
swap are strong-majority female. The makerspace is about two-thirds
male in terms of participants, but far more male in terms of power,
inuence, and the distribution of social status. Race, class, and gender
inequalities are pervasive in these sites, at times even threatening their
viability. Finally—and this is key to many of the dynamics—with the
exception of a few makers who gained their expertise outside the formal
education system, the people we interviewed and studied have dispro-
portionately high education and high parental education levels. This is
what Pierre Bourdieu has called “high cultural capital.
Let’s start with the time bank. The time bank has a very white,
very female membership whose education levels, as well as parental
education levels, are “o the charts” in comparison to the U.S. pop-
ulation. One result is that, despite their ideological alignment with
the goals of the time bank, many members subtly undermine its func-
tioning. They do this by believing that their own time is worth more
than that of others, by failing to oer highly valued skills that they
have (such as computer programming) because they’d rather “work
with their hands,” or because they screen out potential trading part-
ners on account of grammatical errors or less-than-professional pres-
entation on the time banks website. In our research, we found that
people were often unaware of the ways in which their preferences were
undermining the egalitarian goals of the bank. Yet that behavior led to
a volume of trading being far below its potential on account of social
exclusion.
Low trading volume also proved to be a problem for the food
swap. Here, social exclusion took a fairly familiar form: snobbishness
around food. Founders and longer-term members were reluctant to
trade with newcomers whose oerings did not conform to a strong,
albeit unarticulated, ideal. The wrong packaging was often fatal to
one’s chances of nding trading partners. So was oering the wrong
type of foods. How one presented the food, the size of the oerings,
41
and the choice of ingredients were critical to making trades. Including
any processed ingredients, for example, no matter how artfully com-
bined or “re-mixed,” was taboo. In our research, near-moral condem-
nation of oerings that did not conform resulted in a collapse of the
food swap. Newcomers failed to stay as their oerings were rejected.
Even longer-term members eventually stopped coming. Socially
exclusionary practices among a homogeneous, highly educated group
led to the failure of this once-promising social innovation.
The makerspace presented a dierent kind of social dynamic.
Unlike the other two sites, it did have a vibrant community with high
demand for services. Many people took classes or joined as members.
Space was at a premium. On the surface, the site appeared to be highly
successful. But as we did our research, we discovered that it was dom-
inated by a small group of men who vied for status via a strongly
classed set of values. At the core of those values was what Bourdieu has
called “distance from [economic] necessity.” To gain high status at the
makerspace, one had to participate in a status system that denigrated
usefulness and functionality and valued esoterica, eccentricity, and a
certain kind of waste. Makers got status by creating items that would
be destroyed after a single use. They specialized in highly abstruse
sub-cultural knowledge. They created an exclusive community, which
screened out people whose making was ordinary, mundane, or eco-
nomically useful. In that way, quite unintentionally, they created bar-
riers for ordinary people. As a result, the site was culturally and racially
very homogeneous.
In our research on for-prot sharing platforms, we found a more
open trading landscape—it was easier for people to join and make
exchanges. However, we did also nd evidence of discrimination.
Airbnb hosts screened potential guests for educational credentials, evi-
dence of nancial assets, and the like. Some indicated they only wanted
to rent to people like themselves. On the other hand, dynamics of social
exclusion were stronger and more prevalent in the nonprot spaces.
So what’s the lesson of our research for platform cooperativism?
Historically, cooperatives have mostly been formed by working class
42
people who share a lot in terms of culture and history. That shared cul-
ture was crucial to their success. But platform cooperativism is coming
from a dierent social space. If platform co-ops are to succeed without
reproducing their own more privileged class, race, and gender homo-
geneousness, founders and early participants must be highly attuned to
subtle social dynamics that valorize the practices and traits of dominant
groups. Furthermore, they must stop those dynamics from developing.
Practically speaking, achieving that probably means starting with a
diverse group of founders and early participantsat the very least on
the social dimensions of class, race, and gender.
43
8. WORSE THAN CAPITALISM
MCKENZIE WARK
What if this was no longer capitalism, but something worse? Such a
perspective might help explain some of the features of the contempo-
rary political-economic landscape. My argument, odd though it may
sound, is that both capital and labor have lost ground to an emerging
ruling class, one that confronts a quite dierent kind of antagonist.
It helps to see capitalism as already a kind of second-order mode
of commodied production. First-order commodication emerged—
in part, at least—through the transformation of the relations between
peasants and their lords; the peasants lost traditional rights to arable
land and to the commons. In place of the (supposedly) ancient rights
and duties that held between landlord and peasant, in which the peas-
ant’s duties to the lord were paid directly with a share of the produce,
the peasant had to pay rent in cash.
First-order commodication was thus the commodication of
land. Pieces of land became abstract pieces of property that could be
bought and sold. Peasants lost traditional rights to land and saw much
of it enclosed and privatized. A “surplus population” of peasants ended
up in the cities, where they were to become the working class, sellers
of labor-power.
Capitalism was a second-order mode of commodied production,
built on top of the pastoral one that preceded it in the countryside.
One can forget that when David Ricardo wrote On the Principles of
Political Economy and Taxation, he wrote on behalf of a rising, urban,
capitalist ruling class and against the interests of a pre-existing, rural,
pastoralist ruling class. It was a study in intra-ruling class studies.
44
In opposition to the pastoralist ruling class, the capitalist ruling
class constructed a rather more abstract mode of production, one in
which not only land but labor and the factory could be elaborate forms
of fungible private property. With the destruction of the privileges
awarded it by the state, the landlord class became a subordinate ruling
class within capitalism, still extracting its extortionate ground rents (as
indeed it still does today) but unable to claim the whole of the state as
its own and to govern exclusively in its own interests.
The peasantry were, of course, no mere spectators upon their own
oppression, but resisted the landlord class, every so often rising up
against it. However, the peasantry tended toward a politics based on
ancient rights. The rise of the modern labor movement was a cultural
revolution that replaced the backward-looking peasant politics with
a forward-looking one, based on the evident fact of capitalism as the
dominant mode of production.
Such might be a more or less orthodox thumbnail sketch of the
rise of capitalism in Britain, where it rst arose. Of course, elsewhere
in the world it followed dierent paths. But rather than turn toward
the complicated business of pluralizing this historical sketch, I want
to do something dierent: to pose the question of whether there is,
on top of the second-order commodied mode of production of cap-
italism, a third-order commodied mode of production—what I will
call vectoralism.
First-order commodication, what I call pastoralism, made land
into a form of abstract private property relation. Second-order com-
modication, generally called capitalism, much advanced the abstrac-
tion of the private property relation into fungible things. Third-
order commodication, which I call vectoralism, extends abstraction
much further, subordinating information to whole new kinds of pri-
vate property rights, and in the process creating new kinds of class
relations.
On top of the class relation of landlords and peasants, and of cap-
italists and the working class, there is a relation between a vectoralist
class that owns the vector of information in one form or another, and a
45
hacker class that has to produce new forms of information that can be
made into private property.
This emerging class relation does not replace previous layers of
commodied abstraction, but it does transform them. Initially, the
vectoralist class enabled capital to outwit the working class in the class
conicts of the late twentieth century. The information vector was
what enabled capital to route around the power of labor to interrupt
production. The information vector enabled capital to draw resources
from a variety of sources at short notice. The information vector ena-
bled capital to develop productive resources remote from traditional
working class communities, with their historic memory and capacity
for self-organization.
In the short term, the vectoralist class was helpful to capital in its
struggle against labor, but in the long run, it is trying to subordinate
capital to itself. Take a look at the top Fortune 500 companies, or the
top “unicorn” venture capital darlings of the moment. With a few
exceptions, one nds iterations of the same thing: companies whose
power and wealth relies on stocks or ows of information, which con-
trol either the extensive vector over space or the intensive vector of an
archive of commodied informationso-called intellectual property.
Whether it is nance, tech, cars, drugs, food, or chemicals—often
the big companies no longer actually make their products. That can
be contracted out to a competing mass of capitalist suppliers. What the
vectoralist rm owns and controls is brands, patents, copyrights, and
trademarks, or it controls the networks, clouds, and infrastructures,
along which such information might move.
The rise of the so-called sharing economy is really just a logical
extension of this contracting out of actual material services and
labor by rms that control unequal ows of information. This con-
trol via the information vector is becoming more granular, working
now at the level of individual laborers rather than subcontracted rms.
At rst, the vectoral made capitalist rms subordinate. Now, where
they can, the vectoralist class replaces them altogether with individual
subcontractors.
46
Like all previous extensions of the abstraction of private property,
this one too produces its own internal antagonist. And like all pre-
vious antagonists, it never appears in a pure and self-conscious form.
Most peasants tugged the forelock and did what they were told, silently
cursing the lord under their breath. Most workers settled for some job
security and a weekend. Radical class-based movements are rare.
So it comes as no surprise that the hacker class is not particu-
larly conscious or organized or antagonistic either. But its frustrations
are real. The hacker class designs the information tools by which all
human eort is controlled and organized by asymmetrical ows of
information. The hacker can see her or his own job succumbing to this
tendency in the end as well.
The organization of the activity of hackers is built into the form of
code itself. Their eorts are compartmentalized and separated—black-
boxed. They work on alienated tasks just as workers do. Only they do not
work from clock-on to knock-o time. Even when they sleep they work
for the boss. They might in some cases be well paid, but in many instances
they are not. Their skills date quickly, and they are replaced by others.
Hackers wont necessarily respond to the vectoralist class in tradi-
tional labor movement terms. A strike would hardly be eective given
that hackers can’t shut down production. The most frequent forms of
antagonism are more likely changing jobs, or stealing time on the job
for one’s own projects. Of course many dream of start-up glory, but
that dream quickly tarnishes when the hacker gets to see rsthand who
usually cashes out rst in such schemes.
The signicance of platform cooperativism is that it is a movement
that can place itself at the nexus of the interests and experiences of both
workers and hackers. Why not use the specic skills hackers have to
create the means of organizing information, but use it to create quite
other ways of organizing labor? Cooperatives have a long history in the
labor movement; indeed, in their origins, they looked back to forms of
peasant self-organization of the commons.
Why not re-imagine the cooperative on the basis of contem-
porary forms of information vector—but without the information
47
asymmetries that are the basis of vectoralist class power? That seems
like the thread of a political-economic project that both honors past
struggles and also addresses the distinctive form of commodication in
the age of the information vector as a private property relation.
The vectoral political economy is in many ways worse than the
capitalist one. It gives the ruling class of our time unprecedented
wealth amid growing poverty and despoliation. It enables that ruling
class unprecedented exibility in routing around strikes, blockages,
or communal strongholds. It has made the whole planet appear as an
innitely exploitable resource at precisely the moment when it is also
clear that the past products of commodied production are coming
back to haunt us.
And yet every advance in the abstraction of the form of private
property also opens up new perspectives on what may be held in
common, and how the common might counter-organize. The prac-
tical and conceptual experiments of platform cooperativism are a key
moment in the advance of this counter-organizing agenda.
48
9. HOW THE UN-SHARING
ECONOMY THREATENS
WORKERS
STEVEN HILL
The U.S. workforce has been enduring a long downward spiral for
nearly three decades. That’s how long it’s been since American workers,
in aggregate, have had a pay increase. Even as corporate prots are at
an all-time high, with signicant chunks of it parked overseas in tax
havens to avoid being taxed, not many of the benets of that labor
productivity are being returned to domestic shores.
A signicant factor in the decline of the quality of jobs today
has been the increasing reliance by many employers on “non-regular”
employees—a growing army of contractors, freelancers, temps, and
part-timers that form the precarious vanguard in a “freelance society.
Any proposal to revamp platform capitalism and launch platform coop-
erativism is challenged with coming to grips with how technology is
changing the nature of work across an astonishing range of occupa-
tions and industries.
Meet Chris Young, an assembly-line worker at a Nissan man-
ufacturing plant in Tennessee. Young works alongside other Nissan
employees, but he works for a private contractor who now provides
a majority of Nissans workers. Young receives half the salary, less
job security, and fewer safety-net benets than the regular Nissan
employees, even though he does the exact same job.
Auto manufacturers increasingly rely on this kind of two-tiered
system. Nationwide, temps have provided nearly a fth of the job
49
growth since the recession ended. And increasingly, the temps aren’t
very temporary. Some have been employed at the same company for as
long as eleven years, resulting in the doublespeak term “perma-temps.
Microsoft paid $97 million to settle a lawsuit for denying benets to
over eight thousand perma-temps.
Besides temp workers, another type of worker is known as the
independent contractor.” Fritz Elienberg worked for ve years as
a full-time employee installing cable and Internet service for RCN
Corporation in Boston. Elienberg often worked ten to fourteen hours a
day yet he never received time-and-a-half for overtime. When a ladder
fell on his foot and seriously injured it, workers’ compensation would
not cover his medical bills. Why? Because RCN did not regard him as
a regular employee; instead he was an “independent contractor.” That
meant, legally speaking, he worked for himself and was not employed
by RCN. Elienberg sued RCN and the company promptly red him,
adding retaliation to his list of grievances.
The business advantage of using such non-regular workers is
obvious: it can lower labor costs by 30 percent, since the business is
not responsible for providing health benets, Social Security, unem-
ployment or injured workers’ compensation, paid sick leave or vaca-
tion, and more. Contract workers, who are barred from forming labor
unions and have no grievance procedure, can be dismissed without
notice. A small percentage of contract workers, especially in the tech
industry, earn high enough wages to make it all tenable, but most
are helpless tumbleweeds in the erratic labor market of the freelance
society.
Besides the explosion in the number of temporary and contract
jobs, nearly half of the new jobs created in the so-called “recovery”
pay only a bit more than minimum wage. Three-fourths of Americans
are living paycheck to paycheck, with little to no emergency savings
to rely on if they lose their job. Income inequality is now as bad as it
was in 1928, just before the Great Depression. Incredibly, the share of
wealth held by the bottom 90 percent is no higher today than during
our grandparents’ time. It’s as if the New Deal had never existed.
50
RACE TO THE BOTTOM IN THE FREELANCE SOCIETY
Now a new and alarming mash-up of Silicon Valley technology and
Wall Street greed is thrusting upon us the latest economic trend: the
so-called sharing (or gig) economy. Companies like Uber, Instacart,
Upwork, and TaskRabbit allegedly are “liberating workers” to become
independent entrepreneurs” and the “CEOs of their own businesses.
In reality, these workers also are contractors, with little choice but to
hire themselves out for ever-smaller jobs (“gigs”) at low wages and
with no safety net, while the companies prot.
Silicon Valley is redesigning the corporation itself. These gig
companies are little more than a website and an app, with a small
number of executives and regular employees who oversee an army of
freelancers, temps, and contractors. In the vision of the techno gurus
and their Ayn Rand libertarianism, CEOs want a labor force they can
turn o and on like the latest Netix movie.
For example, Upwork is an online business portal that acts
like an eBay for jobs, allowing each worker to hang out a shingle
to attract buyers of their services. A mere eight hundred employees
(two-thirds of whom are contractors) oversee an army of ten million
freelancers from all over the world who compete against each other,
scrounging for jobs in an online labor auction in which the bidders
oering the lowest wages usually win. The types of jobs on the auc-
tion block include website and app designers, software developers, logo
and graphic designers, translators, architects, engineers, and more.
Workers from India, Thailand, and the developing world compete
against developed world workers, undercutting each other’s wages. It’s
a race to the bottom.
As contractors, these workers don’t receive safety-net benets
because they aren’t “employees” of whoever hires them. They also
aren’t paid while they are hustling for their next gig, a never-ending
activity. Increasingly, these sorts of online job brokerages comprise a
bigger chunk of the overall work force. TaskRabbit, CrowdFlower,
Work Market, HourlyNerd (for hiring freelance MBAs), Thumbtack,
51
and Freelancer.com (all of which either currently or in the past have
used a similar online auction price structure) have innitely expanded
the geographic range and size of the contingent labor job applicant
pool.
With wages at, the quality of jobs declining, and the safety net
deteriorating, a whi of desperation has crept into the labor force.
Businesses large and small, whether in the traditional economy or
the sharing economy, are gradually distancing themselves from any
enduring relationship with the workers they hire. “Fissured” work is
an increasingly common feature of our outsourced economy. It’s how
more and more people are working, whether they want to or not.
Welcome to the Freelance Society.
THE UBER-IZATION OF WORK
Uber is the best known of these new kinds of businesses. It is nothing
more than a temp agency, in which the predominant job on oer is
that of a taxi driver (more recently Uber is trying other related services,
such as courier or delivery person). Drivers are not treated as employees
but as freelance contractors, and most drivers, after they subtract their
considerable driving expenses, don’t earn any more than taxis drivers.
Indeed, many Uber drivers complain they don’t earn minimum wage,
much less a living wage. They receive no safety-net benets and can be
cut o the app-based platform at any time. Recently Uber cut o hun-
dreds of drivers (and possibly over a thousand) in Los Angeles and San
Francisco because those drivers’ “acceptance rate” was too low. Many
veteran drivers have gured out that, given the increase in congestion
(in part stemming from the proliferation of ride-sharing vehicles on
the streets), drivers often dont make any money on short rides because
they get stuck in trac. They have begun refusing short rides, so Uber
red drivers it deemed to be oending without warning.
If these workers really are the “CEOs of their own driving busi-
ness,” as Uber likes to claim, shouldn’t they be able to refuse a ride they
52
know will cause them to lose money? This incident and others seem
to support the legal claim by thousands of drivers who are suing Uber,
insisting they are indeed employees under the strict management of
Uber, not sovereign contractors. As an employer, Uber would be
responsible for paying Social Security and Medicare contributions for
these workers, as well as unemployment and injured workers’ compen-
sation and driving expenses. This stark reality also points to the grave
need for the creation of a new ride-sharing platform in which drivers
have more control, either through outright cooperative ownership of
the platform or a binding contract negotiated by a union-type organ-
ization, such as was recently empowered in Seattle via new legislation.
According to Uber’s own numbers, most drivers work only part-
time and leave after a year. New drivers like the exibility, but after a
while they burn out, with frequent wage cuts and unfair treatment. In
January 2016, Uber slashed wages once again, this time by 30 percent
to about 50 cents per mile in some locations (after Ubers 25 percent
cut of each fare is subtracted). If driving for Uber was such a great job
and paid halfway decently, wouldn’t more drivers last longer and drive
more hours?
Many businesses are increasingly relying on these types of oper-
ations as a core part of their prot-maximizing model. If this new
corporate model is left unregulated, it will destroy what remains
of a vibrant middle class. But fortunately there are solutions. One
that I and others have proposed is creating a “universal and portable
safety net.” Each worker should be assigned an “Individual Security
Account” into which every business that hires that worker would pay
a small “safety net fee,” prorated to the number of hours a worker
is employed by that business. Those funds would be used to pay for
each worker’s safety net.
We don’t have to wait for a dysfunctional U.S. Congress to pass
this new kind of deal. State governments and even city councils can
pass it, requiring local businesses to pay into Individual Security
Accounts for each worker. By modernizing the social contract, and
combining that with the creation of cooperative platforms and greater
53
economic democracy that can oer to consumers an alternative to
runaway capitalism, we would take major steps toward forging a world
in which most workers would be enriched by technology and innova-
tion, instead of being disrupted and deprived by a freelance society and
its “share-the-crumbs” economy.
54
10. SPONGEBOB, WHY DON’T
YOU WORK HARDER?
CHRISTOPH SPEHR
As we head once again into a brave new world, this time character-
ized by buzzwords such as “platform” and “mutual” and “decen-
tered,” it is worthwhile to remember the fundamental dierence
between the cordless drill and emancipation. Cordless drills came
into the world as a spin-oof space travel, from there spreading
through earthly households and construction sites. Emancipation,
especially the emancipation of labor, does not. It does not emerge as a
by-product of technological development, and this still holds true in
the age of platforms and algorithmic capitalism. Yes, there are great
possibilities for redening the position of labor in the production
process. Yes, the force is strong in the new means of production, but
so is the dark side.
Should you feel discouraged from opening up a new plat-
form cooperative? No, not at all. But do not expect exploitative,
hierarchical, narrow-minded capitalism to roll over and die just
because youre clever enough to program a platform of your own.
A new mode of production that could release the potential for
a less alienated, less exploited, less asshole-infested worklife will
not prevail just because it seems economically superior. Merely
embracing the change will not be good enough. You can’t win
by just being better. You have to change the rules, which implies
getting organized.
55
WORKING HARDER
SpongeBob: Mr. Krabs, you wanted to ask me a question.
Mr. Krabs: Yes, SpongeBob. Why don’t you work harder?
SpongeBob: I don’t know, Mr. Krabs. I don’t know!
To keep it brief and simple, listen to the master of brief and simple:
SpongeBob SquarePants. In the landmark episode “Imitation Krabs,
the shortest possible explanation of the capitalist-worker relation is
oered when Mr. Krabs poses his most pressing concern: “Spongebob,
why don’t you work harder?”
This is what capitalism is all about: the capitalist (Mr. Krabs) buys
and pays for the worker’s (SpongeBob’s) manpower but owns all of
the product. The harder the worker works, the greater the dierence
between wage and creation of surplus value, the greater the prot. The
bulk of surplus goes to the pockets of the capitalist, enhancing his lead
in social power. Simple, right?
A common method for the capitalist to increase value creation is
handing the worker a tool (in SpongeBob’s case, the spatula and the
secret recipe), enabling the worker to be more productive. The worker
is dependent on the means of production, which are owned by the
capitalist, because the worker can only be productive through them.
Yes, you own a laptop and a mobile phone now; but in analyzing a
mode of production, the decisive question is not who owns any kind of
means of production but who owns the dominant means of production.
These used to be the factory, the machinery. They are now becoming
the big algorithms, the constantly adjusted and ever-developing vir-
tual machinery. If you own them, youre the capitalist. If someone else
owns the majority of your company because you needed investors, or
if you depend on the platforms and algorithms owned by others, you’re
not the capitalist. (You’d “get cash, but they’d get the reins,” as Nathan
Schneider puts it.)
56
PAYING TO BREATHE
Mr. Krabs: Breathe on your own time. I don’t pay you to breathe!
Squidward: (unfolding his pay slip) What is this? You want me to pay for
standing at the cash register?
Mr. Krabs: There’s gonna be a few changes around here.
As passionate SpongeBob fans know, things improve very little in the
Krusty Krab. Even the fabulous turbo-drive spatula from the episode
“Help Wanted” never reappears once the “anchovies situation” is over.
Capital can be quite reluctant to push for progress. It costs a lot of
money, and once everybody has it, the gains in productivity go to the
consumer.
Throughout the history of capitalism, capitalists used to increase
their prots through changes that do not improve the means of pro-
duction but shift costs and burdens from the capitalist to the worker
or the society—for example, by claiming something as capitalist
property that used to be common property. In nineteenth-century
England it was land. In the twenty-rst-century global economy it
is information appropriated by Facebook, Google, and Microsoft. In
proto-industrialization, the cottage system (when the workers had to
work at home) allowed the manufacturer maximum f lexibility,
minimum responsibility, and low wages. Today, ubiquitous plat-
formization does the same. In many cases, its competitiveness
stems only from de-organizing and de-valuing labor.
This is not progress. According to Stephen Marglin (in his famous
essay “What Do Bosses Do?”), a method of production is technologically
superior (“progressive”) only if it produces the same output with less input.
There is no economic superiority in producing something cheaper just by
paying lower wages, by skimming labor costs through unpaid hours or
unrewarded density of work, or by making the worker pay for breathing.
Nevertheless, there is such a thing as progress. It happens even
in capitalism, mostly when labor is organized and society is on alert
for externalization of costs (so that other exits are closed). While
57
competition may work as an incentive to apply progress, it is produced
outside competition: through cooperation, in spaces of non-eciency.
CHANGING THE RULES
SpongeBob: We are workers united! We’re gonna smash that with the
people’s hammer! And we’re gonna…wait…Squidward, what was that
other thing?
Squidward: Dismantle the oppressive system.
SpongeBob: Yeah, that one, too!
Ah, what was that other thing I mentioned above? Wait…yes: you have
to close the exits!
To push for economic transformation, for the cooperatives to take
over, you have to dene the game as ruled by progress. And as we
have learned, this means closing the exits, preventing the possibility of
thriving not by progress but by shifting burdens and costs to workers
and society. This cannot be done individually. Rules are collective,
and obtaining a change of rules means getting organized.
What we have to obtain is a bill of rights for the age of algorithmic
capitalism. First, we need a ght for new labor rights to force back the
new forms of exploitation that are running wild. Workers have a right
to know their fellow workers, especially in platform labor. They have
a right to balanced job packages; to a xed space of self-determined
labor as part of their job (expanding Google’s “20 percent time” to
all workers); to rules-based, democratic governance instead of com-
mand-based management. They have a right to a share in produc-
tivity gains; a right to log o; a right to work without surveillance.
That’s not only trade-union work. Palak Shahs “Good Work Code”
or Trebor Scholz’ principles for platform co-ops are today’s equivalent
to the demand for an eight-hour day.
Second, we need new entrepreneurial rightstoday’s equivalent
to the antitrust lawsto ght back the stiing power of size, nancial
58
markets, and incumbency. Network neutrality and equal rights for
cooperatives are essential, as is equal access to supply, services, pub-
licity, and clouds. Enterprises need a right to set up their own consti-
tutions and to represent their interests in the context of holdings and
investors. As Nathan Schneider writes, “A new economy will need
new public politics to level the playing eld between traditional cor-
porations and collaborative enterprises.
Third, we need a legal framework for a new regime of accu-
mulation. This takes vision; it’s today’s equivalent of what a social-
democratic or socialist economic policy used to be. It means bringing
state and society back in, not only as neutral gatekeepers of economic
fair play but as a volonrale that gives the economy a social purpose
and a base in democratic values. There is nothing neutral about the
actual economy. It is a complicated, systematized eort to reconcile
productivity with the privilege of powerful elites, dominant social
groups, and global coalitions. A democratic, cooperative economy
will likewise be a systematized eort to reconcile productivity with
equality, sustainability, and “the liberation of the productivity of all
(as Bertolt Brecht stated in his lines on the “great production” in his
journals). This might mean public investment, public co-ownership,
and strong incentives for social enterprises.
Some of this might sound slightly awkward to us, since we havent
discussed it for a long time. But we have to have this conversation if
we want to implement cooperativism. I fully agree with Trebor Scholz
when he states: “This isnt about some romantic attachment to the past.
This is about the language of labor and living within it, its cardinal
lesson, which is that in confrontation with the power of the employing class,
individual solutions are not working.” Or, as one person in the audience
at the Platform Cooperativism conference put it: “Please shut up and
grow some class consciousness.
59
11. PORTABLE REPUTATION IN
THE ON-DEMAND ECONOMY
KATI SIPP
While the app-based gig economy derives a certain sexiness from its
association with the tech world, the gig economy has existed oine for
generations. Some workers have been pushed into the gig economy by
circumstances beyond their control, while others have always chosen
and will continue to choose it, either due to the nature of their occu-
pations or for personal reasons. Workers in gig situations get new jobs
through the strength of their reputations; the dierence in the on-de-
mand economy is that workers don’t own their reputations.
“Just like domestic workers were tucked away in people’s houses,
digital laborers remain invisible, tucked away in between algorithms,
said Trebor Scholz in his opening talk at the Platform Cooperativism
conference. This observation resonated with me, because I worked for
many years with homecare workers and their allies in the disability
rights movement, who have the slogan “Invisible No More.” One of
the big dierences between domestic workers and platform workers
(especially online-only platforms like Amazon’s Mechanical Turk) is
that the domestic workers have word of mouth, and references, and do
work that is geographically located in a specic place.
Most of us employed in traditional jobs have things like resumes,
coworkers that we can rely on for references, networks of people who
will tell us about jobs, and other advantages that help when were
looking for new work. I personally have changed jobs twice in the past
two years, and both times I took my reputation with me—through
word of mouth, through work-related networks, and yes, through
60
LinkedIn recommendations. In some ways, the platform economy has
the potential to be wildly democratizing, because more transparent
networks for nding work should mean larger numbers of people get-
ting new opportunities.
Many of these platforms don’t let workers have any control over
their reputations. I don’t want to sugarcoat the problems of reputa-
tion for workers with traditional jobs, but in some ways reputation is
much more punishing for platform workers. There have been many
stories about Airbnb, Uber, and others removing workers from their
platforms, with little to no notice or ability to correct problems. In
fact, Uber drivers are required to maintain a certain rating in order
to stay on the platform—a fact that few passengers know. Workers in
most cases lack the ability to challenge the stain on their reputations,
and sometimes they don’t even know why their reputations might
have suered. Platforms are highly dependent on customer ratings for
policing the quality of their workforce, but they haven’t gured out
how to correct for those same customers’ race and gender biases. It can
feel to the worker like it’s “one strike and youre out”and that arbi-
trariness just adds to the instability of gig work. In addition, reputation
isn’t portable. If Uber drivers want to change platforms and start deliv-
ering packages for Instacart, they have to start from scratch to build up
a good reputation on the new siteeven though they are using skills
that are valuable to both sites.
It doesn’t have to be this way, and the oine gig economy reminds
us of that.
Meet my friend Dave. Dave is an actor who lives in New York
City. The nature of acting is contingent—even the longest-running
Broadway musical will come to an end long before the end of an indi-
vidual actor’s career. The same is true for movies, TV shows, commer-
cial work, recording audio books, and Shakespeare in the Park (or, in
his case, Shakespeare in the Parking Lot).
Like most gig workers, Dave has multiple sources of income
throughout the yearand to supplement them, he also works as a
catering bartender. In years when he books more acting work, he
61
might bartend less, but he’s been a steady bartender for a long time.
Catering is itself seasonal work. There’s lots to do in December, when
rich people or companies are having their holiday parties, but much
less in January. Catering managers know him, and they know he’s reli-
able. They keep calling him for jobs, even in years when he might be
turning them down frequently for acting gigs.
For Dave, one part of the solution to his “gig” insecurity is his
union, the Screen Actors Guild–American Federation of Television
and Radio Artists, or SAG-AFTRA. The union negotiates multi-
employer agreements within different industry sectorsso the
contract for TV commercial work in New York is different from
the contract for recording audio books—but all the employers pay
into common health, benefits, and pension funds, on a per capita
basis. If Dave books a one-day commercial shoot, the ad agency
pays less into the pension than if he books a recurring role on a
TV show, of course, but all the money goes into one pension that
Dave will eventually be able to retire on.
It’s important for folks in the platform-cooperative community to
understand that there are existing worker-led organizations that are set
up to deal with multi-employer, disaggregated work situationsand
that we can build from their model, rather than starting from scratch.
Not every union was set up to deal with jobs in which workers stayed
with the same company for years on end. Lots of people are starting
to think about ways that workers can organize in the gig economy—
and I want to urge all of them to think about how to build reputation
best-practices into their eorts. A decent reputation system should be:
Worker-controlled
Transparent
Reparable
Able to take input from multiple companies (if that is relevant
to the worker)
Resistant to bias and prejudice
Fair in how it distributes rewards
62
Correctable with improved behavior
Equipped with some kind of a grievance process
Dave’s union was formed the old-fashioned way. Actors struck
in Hollywood in 1929, and then radio producers in 1939. The tech-
nological tools that actors have worked with have changed over the
years—and the union has transitioned with the new technology. Now,
for instance, it is organizing workers who voice video games, guring
out how to deal with new channels for distribution of content like
YouTube and Hulu, and taking on the digital advertising industry.
SAG-AFTRA hasn’t had to “solve” the reputation problem in the way
that online platform worker organizations will—but that is because
they are dealing with employers who want to see actors’ work through
auditions before they cast them. We don’t get to ask to see samples
of our TaskRabbit’s work assembling Ikea furniture; we choose them
based on their on-site ratings instead. Dave still relies on reputation in
his catering work, but that’s delivered through his existing (and oine)
personal network.
We are already seeing tech companies develop ways of aggre-
gating our online reputations—through sites like LinkedIn, Karma,
MakerBase, and Work Hands—but those platforms still haven’t caught
up to the best-practices of the oine gig economy. And let’s be honest;
you wouldn’t want a union that just exists to protect workers’ repu-
tations, just as we don’t organize oine unions only around issues of
worker reputation.
Those of us who are striving to organize workers in the online
economy have to build a theory for reputation portability and pro-
tection into our other organizing work. We can’t let reputation man-
agement become disaggregated from the platforms on which workers
get work. So build a better mousetrap. We should take a lesson from
Dave’s union too, and build organizations that can evolve as the tech-
nology work evolves.
63
12. COUNTERANTI-
DISINTERMEDIATION
DMYTRI KLEINER
In Chapter 33 of Capital, Karl Marx introduces us to the character of
Mr. Peel, recounted from E. G. Wakeelds England and America:
A Comparison of the Social and Political State of Both Nations. Although
Mr. Peel’s story is one of early nineteenth-century colonialism, it
helps us understand what has become of the Internet and the so-called
sharing economy.
Mr. Peel went to Swan River in Australia to seek his fortune.
He brought everything an aspiring capitalist might need to start
accumulating surplus value and become a great capitalist: three
hundred people, including men, women, and children, to provide
the labor and its reproduction, along with £50,000, a large sum at
the time.
However, things didn’t work out for Mr. Peel, as Marx concludes,
“Unhappy Mr. Peel who provided for everything except the export of
English modes of production to Swan River!”
Once arrived in Swan River, the three hundred people simply
went o and settled on the vast amounts of free land available, and
“Mr. Peel was left without a servant to make his bed or fetch him water
from the river.
He discovered that capital is not a thing but a social relation
between persons, established by the instrumentality of things.
As Marx explains further, “Property in money, means of sub-
sistence, machines, and other means of production, does not as yet
stamp a man as a capitalist if there be wanting the correlative—the
64
wage-worker, the other man who is compelled to sell himself of his
own free will.
Marx argues, “The means of production and subsistence, while
they remain the property of the immediate producer, are not cap-
ital. They become capital only under circumstances in which they
serve at the same time as means of exploitation and subjection of the
laborer.
Mr. Peel’s capitalist class was not satised with their inability to
expand their mode of production into the colonies, and found a solution
in enclosure, described by Wakeeld as “Systematic Colonialization.
Land was seized by law as public property and privatized, with no
free land available. Only those with wealth could be owners, and thus
everybody else needed to sell their labor to capitalists.
The early Internet was like Swan River. How can the modern Mr.
Peel make money operating Internet platforms, if anybody can do so?
If all the software and the networks were open and widely available,
then nobody could really make signicant prot. If the means of pro-
duction are available to all, then there can be no capital.
Like the colonies, the Internet needed to be systematically colo-
nized in order to create the conditions needed by capital. This was also
accomplished by enclosure. The original infrastructure was taken over
and brought under capital control, and decentralized systems were dis-
placed with centralized systems.
“Social media” and “sharing” platforms are two forms of this cen-
tralization, two business models for platform capitalism.
SURPLUS VALUE VS. SURPLUS PROFIT
It’s tempting to look at sites like Facebook and YouTube and conclude
that they earn their prots by exploiting their own users, who generate
all the content that makes the sites popular. However, this is not the
case, because the media is not sold and therefore makes no prot and
captures no value.
65
What is sold is advertisement, thus the paying customers are the
advertisers, and what is being sold are the users themselves, not their
content.
This means that the source of value that becomes Facebooks
prots is the work done by the workers in the global elds and factories,
who are producing the commodities being advertised to Facebooks
audience.
The prots of the media monopolies are formed after surplus value
has already been extracted. Their users are not exploited, but sub-
jected, captured as audience, and instrumentalized to extract surplus
prots from other sectors of the ownership class.
Sharing economy companies like Uber and Airbnb, which own
no vehicles or real-estate, capture prots from the operators of the cars
and apartments for which they provide the marketplace.
Neither of these business models is very new. Media businesses
selling audience commodity are at least as old as commercial radio.
Marketplace landlords, capturing rents from market vendors, have
been with us for centuries.
Rather than subvert capitalism, “sharing” platforms have been
captured by it.
CONSENT-ORIENTED ARCHITECTURE
Capitalist platforms based on the sale of audience commodity and cap-
turing marketplace rents demand a sacrice of privacy and autonomy.
Audience commodity, like all commodities, is sold by measure
and grade. Eggs are sold in dozens as grade “A.” An advertiser might
buy audience commodity by thousands of clicks from middle-aged
white men who own a car and have a good credit rating with a certain
measuree.g., 10,000 clicks.
Audience commodity is graded by what is known about the audi-
ence’s demographics. Platforms with business models that sell audi-
ence commodity require surveillance. Likewise, platforms that capture
66
marketplace rents collect extensive data on their users and providers in
order to maximize the protability of the platform.
A mandatory sacrice of consent is required to use the platforms.
When a user shares information on the platform, they may consent to
sharing that information with certain people, but they don’t neces-
sarily consent to that information being available to the platform’s sta,
to advertisers, or to business partners and state intelligence. Yet for
most users there are no practical alternatives, and they must sacrice
such consent in order to use the platform.
Corporations built to maximize prots are unable to build
consensual platforms. Their business model depends fundamentally on
surveillance and behavioral control.
True consensual platforms should have privacy, security, and
anonymity as core features.
The most eective way to ensure consent is to ensure that all user
data and control of all user interaction resides with the software run-
ning on the user’s own computer, and not on any intermediary servers.
COUNTERANTIDISINTERMEDIATION
On her blog, Wendy M. Grossman writes, “‘Disintermediation’ was
one of the buzzwords of the early 1990s. The Net was going to elim-
inate middlemen by allowing us all to deal with each other directly.
Today, the landscape is dominated by many fewer, much larger ISPs
whose xed connections are far more trackable and controllable. We
thought a lot about encryption as a protector of privacy and, I now
think, not enough about the unprecedented potential for endemic
wiretapping that would be enabled by an increasingly centralized
Internet.
The idea of disintermediation was central to the emancipa-
tory visions of the Internet, yet the landscape today is more medi-
ated than ever before. If we want to think more about the conse-
quences of an increasingly centralized Internet, we need to start by
67
addressing the cause of this centralizing. The Internet was colonized
by capitalist platforms; centralization is required to capture prot.
Disintermediating platforms were ultimately reintermediated by
capitalist investors dictating that communications systems be built
to capture prot.
The aw was, to some degree, a result of the architecture of the
early Internet. The systems that people used in the early Internet were
mainly cooperative and decentralized, but they were not end-to-end.
Users of email services and Usenet, the two most used platforms, did
not generally operate their own servers, on their own local computers,
but were dependent on servers run by others.
Servers require upkeep. Operators need to nance hosting and
administration. As the Internet grew beyond its relatively small early
base, Internet service came to be provided by capitalist corporations,
rather than public institutions, small businesses, or universities. Open,
decentralized services came to be replaced by private, centralized
platforms. The prot interests of the platform nanciers resulted in a
policy of antidisintermediation.
Just as systematic colonialization was developed to establish the
capitalist mode of production in the colonies, antidisintermediation
was developed to colonize cyberspace.
The basic strategy of antidisintermediation was formulated by
economists like Carl Shapiro and Hal R. Varian. Their inuential book
Information Rules encourages platform owners to pursue “lock-in.” As
they summarize on their website, “Since information technology
products work in systems, switching any single product can cost users
dearly. The lock-in that results from such switching costs confers a
huge competitive advantage to rms that manage their installed base
of customers eectively.
Their advice was well received. Varian is currently chief econo-
mist of Google, while Shapiro was a deputy assistant attorney general
for economics in the Department of Justice.
Going back to an early Internet architecture of cooperative, decen-
tralized servers, as projects like Diaspora, GNU Social, and others are
68
attempting to do, will not work. This is precisely the sort of architec-
ture that antidisintermediation was designed to defeat.
Decentralized systems need to be designed to be counteranti-
disintermediationist.
Central to the counterantidisintermediationist design is the end-
to-end principle; platforms must not depend on servers and admins,
even when cooperatively run, but must, to the greatest degree possible,
run on the computers of the platforms users.
The computational capacity and network access of the users’ own
computers must make up the resources of the platform, so that on
average each new users adds more resources to the platform than they
consume.
By keeping the computational capacity in the hands of the users,
we prevent the communication platform from becoming capital,
and we prevent the users from being instrumentalized as audience
commod ity.
Thus, we leave Mr. Peel just as unhappy in cyberspace as he was
in Swan River, resisting the colonization of our communication plat-
forms by venture capital and paving the way for venture communism.
69
13. FROM OPEN ACCESS TO
DIGITAL COMMONS
DAVID BOLLIER
We are accustomed to regarding open platforms as synonymous with
greater freedom and innovation. But as we have seen with the rise
of Google, Facebook, and other tech giants, open platforms that are
dominated by large corporations are only “free” within the bounda-
ries of market norms and extractive business models. Yes, open plat-
forms provide many valuable services at no (monetary) cost to users.
But when some good or service is oered at no cost, it really means
that the user is the product. In this case, our personal data, attention,
social attitudes, lifestyle behavior, and even our digital identities are
the commodity to which platform owners are seeking unrestricted
access.
In this sense, many open platforms are not so benign. Many of
them are techno-economic fortresses, bolstered by structural dynamics
that enable dominant corporate players to monopolize and monetize a
given sector of online activity. Market power based on such platforms
can then be used to carry out surveillance of users’ lives; erect barriers
to open interoperability and sharing, sometimes in anti-competitive
ways; and quietly manipulate the content and experience that users
may have on such platforms.
Such outcomes on seemingly open platforms should not be
entirely surprising; they represent the familiar quest of capitalist mar-
kets to engineer the acquisition of exclusive assets and mine them for
private gain. The quarry in this case is our consciousness, creativity,
and culture. The more forward-looking segments of capital realize
70
that owning a platform (with stipulated, but undecipherable, terms
of use) can be far more lucrative than owning exclusive intellectual
property rights for content.
So for those of us who care about freedom in an elemental human
and civic sense—beyond the narrow mercantilist “freedoms” oered
by capitalist markets—the critical question is how to preserve certain
inalienable human freedoms and shared cultural spaces. Can our free
speech, freedom of association, and freedom to innovate ourish if the
dominant network venues must rst satisfy the demands of investors,
corporate boards, and market metrics?
If we are serious about protecting human freedoms that have a
life beyond markets, I believe we must begin to develop new modes
of platform cooperativism that go beyond standard forms of corporate
control. We need to pioneer technical, organizational, and nancial
forms that enable users to mutualize the benets of their own online
sharing. We must be able to avoid the coerced and undisclosed sur-
render of personal information and digital identity to third-parties
who may or may not be reliable stewards of such information.
There are other reasons to move to commons-based platforms.
As David P. Reed showed in a seminal 1999 paper, “That Sneaky
Exponential,” the value generated by networks increases exponen-
tially as interactions move from a broadcasting model based on “best
content” to a network of peer-to-peer transactions. The most valu-
able networks, however, are those that facilitate group aliations to
pursue shared goals—which is to say, networks that are treated like
commons.
Reed found that the value of such “group forming networks,” in
which people have the tools for “free and responsible association for
common purposes,” to be 2
n
, where n is the number of members in
the network. That’s a fantastically powerful growth curve. His analysis
suggests that the value generated by Facebook, Twitter, and other pro-
prietary network platforms remains highly rudimentary because par-
ticipants have only limited tools for developing trust and condence
71
in each other. In short, the value potential of the commons has been
deliberately stied as part of the business model.
For all of these reasons, our imaginations and aspirations must
begin to shift their focus from open platforms to digital commons.
Self-organized commoners must be able to control the terms of their
interactions and governance, and to reap the fruits of their own col-
laboration and sharing.
From open access platforms to managed digital commons: that is one of
the chief challenges that network-based peer production must meet if
we are going to unleash the enormous value that distributed, autono-
mous production can create.
A variety of legal and technological innovations are now starting
to address the structural limits of (market-nanced) open platforms
as vehicles for commoning. These initiatives remain somewhat emer-
gent, yet they are lled with great promise.
THE POTENTIAL OF THE BLOCKCHAIN
One instrument for converting open platforms into digital commons is
the blockchain ledger, the software innovation that lies at the heart of
the Bitcoin digital currency network. Although Bitcoin itself has been
designed to serve familiar capitalist functions (tax avoidance, private
accumulation through speculation), the blockchain ledger is signi-
cant because it can enable highly reliable, versatile forms of collective
action on open networks. It does this by validating the authenticity of
a digital object (for example, a bitcoin) without the need for a third-
party guarantor such as a bank or government body.
This solves a particularly dicult collective-action problem in
an open network context: How do you know that a given digital
object—a bitcoin, a legal document, digital certicate, dataset, a vote,
or a digital identity asserted by an individual—is the real thing and
not a forgery? By using a searchable online ledger that keeps track of
all transactions, blockchain technology solves this problem by acting
72
as a kind of permanent record maintained by a vast, distributed peer
network. This makes it far more secure than data kept at a centralized
location, because the authenticity of its records are registered among
so many nodes in the network that it is virtually impossible to corrupt.
Because of these capabilities, blockchain technology could provide
a critical infrastructure for building what are called “distributed col-
laborative organizations” (sometimes called “distributed autonomous
organizations”). These are essentially self-organized online commons.
A DCO could use blockchain technology to give its members specied
rights within the organization, which could be managed and guaran-
teed by the blockchain. These rights, in turn, could be linked to the
conventional legal system to make the rights legally cognizable and
enforceable.
One rudimentary example of how the blockchain might be
used to facilitate a commons: In the United States, former Federal
Communications Commission Chairman Reed Hundt has proposed
using blockchain technology to create distributed networks of solar
power on residential houses coordinated as commons. The ledger
would keep track of how much energy a given homeowner generates
and shares with others, and consumes. In eect, the system would
enable the ecient organization of decentralized solar grids, together
with a “green currency” that could serve as a medium of exchange
within solar microgrids or networks, helping to propel adoption of
solar panels. The blockchain amounts to a network-based architecture
for enabling commons-based governance.
SMART TRANSACTIONS
This eld of experimentation may yield another breakthrough tool for
forging digital commons: smart contracts. These are dynamic software
modules operating in an architecture of shared protocols (much like
TCP/IP or HTTP) that could enable new types of group governance,
decision-making, and rules-enforcement on open network platforms.
73
We are already familiar with rudimentaryand corporate-
oriented versions—of this idea, such as digital rights management, a
system that gives companies the ability to constrain how users may use
their legally purchased technologies, from movies on DVD to ebooks.
As the power of networked collaboration has become clear, however,
many tech innovators now recognize that the real challenge is not how
to lock up and privatize digital artifacts, but how to assure that they
can be reliably shared on open platforms in legally enforceable ways,
for the benet of a dened group of contributors or for everyone.
There are now many active eorts underway to devise technical
systems for deploying “smart” legal agents whose transactions would
also be enforceable under conventional law. These transactions could,
of course, be used to invent new types of markets, but they also could
be used to create new types of commons. Ultimately, the two realms
may bleed into each other and create social hybrids that conjoin com-
munity commitments and market activity.
A related realm of software innovation is trying to blend familiar
cooperative structures with open network platforms to enable collec-
tive deliberation and governance—“commoning”through online
systems. Some of the more notable experiments include Loomio,
DemocracyOS, and LiquidFeedback. Each of these seeks to enable
members of online networks to carry on direct, sustained, and some-
what complicated discussions, and then to clarify group sentiment
and reach decisions that participants see as binding, legitimate, and
meaningful.
NETWORKS OF PEER PRODUCERS
In a natural extension of such capacities, open value networks, or
OVNs, are attempts to enable bounded networks of participants to
carry out crowdfunding, crowdsourcing of knowledge, and co-
budgeting among their identiable participants. OVNs such as Enspiral
and Sensorica have been described as an “operating system for a new
74
kind of organization” and a “pilot project for the new economy.
These enterprises consist of digital platforms that facilitate new modes
of decentralized and self-organized social governance, production, and
livelihoods among members of distinct communities. The networks
are organized in ways that let anyone contribute to the project and be
rewarded based on their contributions—as measured by actual con-
tributions, experience, and other collectively determined criteria.
Unlike most commons, which are intended to serve household or
community needs, not market gain (e.g., commons for water, urban
spaces, open access publishing, FabLabs, and makerspaces), open value
networks have no reservations about engaging with markets; users
of OVNs simply wish to maintain their organizational and cultural
integrity as commons-based peer producers. This means open,
horizontal, and large-scale cooperation and coordination; responsible
stewardship of the shared wealth and assets while allowing individual
access, use, authorship, and ownership of resources where appropriate;
careful accounting of individual inputs and outcomes via a common
ledger system; and the distribution of fair rewards based on individual
contributions to the project.
These initiatives to create new technical, organizational, and
nancing opportunities for platform cooperativism are still emerging.
They will require further experimentation and development to make
them fully functional and scalable. Yet they promise to furnish attrac-
tive, potentially breakthrough alternatives to centralized, prot-
centric platforms. By providing more trustworthy systems for genuine
commoning and user sovereignty, these new forms could soon enable
digital commonsand hybrid forms of user-driven markets—to
surpass the value-creating capacities of conventional open platforms.
PART 3
AN INTERNET OF
OUR OWN
77
SHOWCASE 1: PLATFORMS
What would it be like to use a cooperave Internet? How would we
interact with it dierently? How would we protect our rights and meet
our needs? These projects answer such quesons in a variety of ways.
While not all are formal co-ops, they replicate exisng tools in fairer
forms, in addion to imagining new possibilies that cooperaon
makes possible. Some are sll lile more than an idea, while others
are earning millions of dollars in revenue. But they all demonstrate
that plaorm cooperavism is under way already.
78
Project Name: Stocksy United
Completed by: Nuno Silva & Brianna Welaufer
Locaon: Victoria, Brish Columbia
URL: stocksy.com
Stocksy is a stock photo agency providing royalty-free licenses on exclu-
sive photos via an online marketplace that provides sustainable careers
to photographers through co-ownership, prot sharing, and transparent
business pracces. Our content is curated to challenge the status quo
of stock photos. We’re very selecve of our photos and our members in
order to provide a premium product at an accessible price-point.
Each member owns an equal vong share in the company. We’re
organized into three classes: founders and advisors, sta, and photogra-
phers. Daily operaons are managed by execuve sta and employees
in a at decision-making structure to encourage ownership and enthu-
siasm for each individuals contribuons. Our board includes directors
from each class. Any member can propose resoluons. Annual general
meengs are held to report, discuss, and vote on the business and
strategy.
We’re growing at a sustainable and controllable rate. Our founders
knew that growing too fast can oen lead to distracons from core
values. Markeng has been modest; we let our aesthec and word of
mouth be the most signicant driving factor for acquision. Tech and
product development grow out of necessity with an understanding of
whats required to remain compeve and with careful thinking about
how things could be done beer and more eciently given our limited
resources. Our greatest innovaons have come from listening to our
customers and knowing how to do more with less.
Growth has exceeded projecons year aer year. We have a great
reputaon in the industry as having a premium brand and enviable
membership. Our members are seeing some of the highest revenues
theyve ever seen; they will receive annual dividends that account
for 90 percent of the companys prot. In a few years we’ll launch
video licensing and begin developing an innovave search soluon for
nding the perfect image.
79
Project Name: Fairmondo
Completed by: Felix Weth
Locaon: Berlin, Germany
URL: fairmondo.com
Fairmondo is an online marketplace owned by its users. It is open to
businesses as well as individuals, with no general restricons on what
products and services can be oered, except for illegal oers or oers
deemed unacceptable by our members. By contrast, through the pos-
ive promoon of products that fulll a set of criteria for “fairness,”
Fairmondo makes it easy for users to shop in line with their values.
These criteria are constantly open for discussion and improvement by
members and the broader user base.
Founded in Germany in 2012, Fairmondo is a mul-stakeholder
cooperave with open membership for every person who feels
aected by its acvies. Its statutes include a legally binding com-
mitment to uncompromising transparency and democrac account-
ability. The managing board is elected by the employees, to ensure a
culture of mutual respect within the operang team.
In September 2013, we launched the German marketplace run-
ning on our self-developed open source plaorm. To start o, we
focused on building a network of sellers to make the marketplace
valuable to customers. Currently, it oers over two million products,
the majority being books and media arcles. For nancing, we aimed
at keeping the business 100 percent in the hands of the crowd. Over
2,000 members invested over €600,000 to make it happen. While this
approach lends credibility, it also brings obvious challenges when it
comes to scaling.
Our next step is pushing forward: bringing Fairmondo to other
countries, in the form of autonomous co-ops owned by local users.
Through sharing resources on technical development and outreach,
we collaborate toward the goal of creang a true mulnaonal coop-
erave, strong enough to challenge the big players in e-commerce.
80
Project Name: Coopify
Completed by: Steven Lee
Locaon: New York City
URL: coopify.org
The goal of Coopify is to empower and assist low-income worker
cooperave members and entrepreneurs through the power of tech-
nology. It provides three key benets. First, Coopify creates a brand
for the marketplace designed to engage consumers to hire low-income
members of cooperave businesses, such as home-care workers and
movers. This, in turn, drives the second benet: more work for exisng
cooperave members and the ability to onboard new members into
the cooperave. More worker members means a faster path to sus-
tainability and increased purchasing power for cooperaves. And,
third, Coopify will simplify tasks for cooperave members. Currently,
cooperave members have lile to no technology tailored to their
needs and oen rely on manual organizaon and phone calls to book
appointments, receive payment, aend trainings, and other tasks.
Coopify eliminates these cumbersome processes by allowing mem-
bers to interface with the plaorm in their nave language (such as
Spanish or Mandarin), respond to customer requests by texts, manage
their own schedules, and receive payment—all on their smartphone.
Currently, the plan is to turn Coopify itself into a cooperave,
with shared ownership and governance.
There are three priority areas. We need to build the plaorm.
We need to sell the plaorm to potenal cooperaves who might
be willing to join. And we need to market the plaorm to potenal
consumers.
We’re starng small with a community—cooperaves—that
already has a built-in consumer base. We make their jobs easier and
hope to bring in more consumers. Going forward, wed like Coopify to
be the go-to plaorm for New Yorkers to book services.
81
Project Name: Grapay
Completed by: Chad Whitacre
Locaon: Global, with headquarters in Ambridge, Pennsylvania
URL: grapay.com
Grapay oers payments and payrolls for open organizaons via the
Internet. Our value proposion is that we enable open organizaons
to comply with the global nancial and legal system. We compete on
mission because we ourselves are an open organizaon, and we com-
pete on cost because our fees are pay-what-you-want through our
own plaorm.
As a legal enty, Grapay is an LLC with a minimal set of owners,
just enough to get by. As an open organizaon in the free and open-
source soware tradion, Grapay is a benevolent dictatorship that
shares power broadly through public, open decision-making on the
Internet. Anyone willing to behave well is free to voluntarily collab-
orate in our work and share in our revenue. (See inside.grapay.com
for details.)
Grapay is funded from revenue. Our interest in growing faster
than revenue allows is oset by our diculty ng into tradional
capitalist or philanthropic boxes, by wariness of greed, and by the
example of successfully bootstrapped companies.
Grapay has processed over $1 million since we launched four
years ago. We’re proud of this modest accomplishment, because
we’ve achieved it while pioneering an open organizaon in a heavily
regulated industry. We’re even prouder of the way our open organ-
izaon has enabled people to nd not just economic support, but
meaning and purpose in a voluntary community of work—a commu-
nity that has already survived several existenal threats together.
Today, we process about $5,000 per month for about 150 projects
and organizaons. We don’t know how big we’re supposed to get,
nor how fast we’re supposed to get there. Our goal over the next
few years is to stay faithful to our mission: to culvate an economy
of gratude, generosity, and love.
82
Project Name: FairCoop
Completed by: Enric Duran
Locaon: Earth
URL: fair.coop
FairCoop is not about oering a specic service but building a full eco-
nomic ecosystem for a postcapitalist society. In this sense, the eco-
system is what is going to be oered, oering individuals, collecves,
cooperaves, and social companies a set of tools for connecng with
and supporng each other and anyone aiming to make real, radical
social change.
FairCoop does not have a legal enty at the moment, so there
is not a legal basis for ownership. FairCoin is a peer-to-peer crypto-
currency based in free soware, so in that sense nobody owns it;
everyone who has some faircoins and runs the wallet soware is part
of the decentralized ownership of the currency system. Governance
takes place in an open, parcipatory process through online assem-
blies every month and open discussions that can be accessed at the
Fair.Coop site.
Openness is the main characterisc of the FairCoop development.
Developers and acvists with strong will are the main elements for
building our iniaves and this community involvement and backing
signicantly helps nancial costs. The cooperaon and horizontal con-
text are also important to take into account. The nancial dicules for
the cooperave acvity have been resisted parally using the FairCoin
monetary hack, and we are organizing to add dierent mechanisms of
economic disobedience to generate constant incomes for the common
good.
FairCoop is sll in early development stages, but step by step
we are building the ecosystem. For example, FairMarket is an online
marketplace. Aside from our main focus we hope to extend the local
nodes network, which is the main infrastructure needed for deploying
resources at the community level, specially the FairFunds, which con-
sists of 20 percent of all the faircoins in circulaon, and which will
be distributed to commons-producing projects when the network
becomes strong enough.
83
Project Name: Members Media, Ltd. Cooperave
Completed by: Robert Benjamin
Locaon: Portland, Oregon
URL: membersmedia.net
Members Media is the equivalent of the Studio System for inde-
pendent lm and TV. Our direcve is to increase the quality, quanty,
and value of independent narrave media, and give the audience a true
voice in the creaon of content that is produced for their consumpon.
Members Media oers development and producon, as well as sup-
port, to aspiring micro-budget lmmakers from diverse communies.
The ulmate goal is to connect a large supporng audience with a slate
of high-quality, independently produced narrave content through an
online and mobile plaorm that is majority-owned by the users.
Members Media is a mul-stakeholder Limited Cooperave
Associaon or “Balanced Ownership Cooperave.” There are four classes
of patron owners (Supporter, Collaborator, Creator, and Mentor) and two
classes of investor owners (Investor and Builder). The organizaon strives
for the “golden mean,” balance between the interests of each member
class and the overall health of the cooperave. A comprehensive set of
founding documents provide the framework for how the community
interacts and supports each others eorts. During the startup phase the
Investor and Builder classes exercise greater control. As patron member-
ship thresholds are met, majority control transfers to the patron member-
ship classes.
Members Media is sll in the early stages of plaorm develop-
ment. Thus far, narrave support iniaves have been piloted through
exisng plaorms and services. There is a need for applicaons and
plaorm funcons specically designed for the demands of the inde-
pendent narrave community. We are currently fundraising in order
to complete the build of the phase-one plaorm.
Members Media is proving the power of cooperave pracces in
the creaon of independent narrave media. With more resources we
will also show the power of cooperave audience engagement. Our
goal in the coming years is to host a vibrant narrave media commu-
nity with members worldwide and to provide a home to stellar inde-
pendent narrave work.
84
Project Name: TimesFree
Completed by: Francis Jervis (CEO, founder)
Locaon: San Francisco, California
URL: mesfree.co
TimesFree is a plaorm for swapping services between trusted friends
without using cash.
Babysing co-ops swap sits between families using a simple
token system. Theyve been tried and tested for over y years.
Sharers save over $1,000 a year compared to families who hire casual
siers. But running a co-op with spreadsheets and an email list takes
up too much me. As well as taking care of all that administraon,
TimesFree will oer comprehensive safety coverage. Members will be
protected by identy vericaon, background checks and insurance.
Just xing babysing will make life beer for millions of families, but
co-ops oer a perfect model for sharing everyday services like dog
walking and other errands too.
TimesFree is currently privately held and will be working toward
benet corporaon status to help us connue to both serve our mem-
bers as eecvely as possible, and make safe and ecient coopera-
ve, cash-free sharing available to everyone.
So far, the company has been bootstrapped. I built the iOS app
(released in August 2015) in Swi, with a MongoDB-hosted back end.
A version for the Web and Android are next.
Delivering a user experience thats as good or beer than “sharing
economy plaorms like Airbnb, and handling user data—especially
identy and reputaon informaon, once we start oering services
like background checks—are my biggest priories for developing the
next iteraons of the service. The “sharing economy” so far has g-
ured out how to make cooperaon easy and safe, and its me to build
plaorms for real sharing on that scale or bigger. We’re only beginning
to see the possibilies for real, money-free sharing plaorms, and Im
sll learning how creave people can be in what they want to share!
85
Project Name: Snowdri.coop
Completed by: Aaron Wolf
Locaon: Earth (incorporated in Michigan)
URL: snowdri.coop
This book took me to write, edit, and promote. To fund such work, pub-
lishers use legal and technical restricons to make access exclusive to
those who pay. Funding is necessary, but restricons have terrible side-
eects, including blocking sharing, discouraging derivave work, and
excluding people—ulmately, liming the works value. Snowdri.coop is
developing a plaorm to fund creave projects without arcial restric-
ons such as those listed above. Our matching pledge creates a network
eect: each patron’s monthly donaon to their favorite projects is based
on others joining them, such as a pledge of $1 for every 1,000 patrons.
This exible approach minimizes risk and maximizes collecve impact.
As a mul-stakeholder co-op, we propose three member classes:
the worker class made of employees of the plaorm itself; the pro-
ject class made up of those funding their creave work; the general
class made up of users who only donate. As the products are public
goods, the only exclusive value of co-op membership will be in
decision-making. Each class will have Board representaves, and
policy votes put to members will require approval from all classes.
As a nonprot, we have no stock; to get co-op membership, a user
pledges to the plaorm itself as a project.
Everything we do aligns with cooperave values including using
exclusively free/libre/open resources. We use the Haskell-based Yesod
web framework, create illustraons with Inkscape, and communicate
with Jitsi Meet and IRC. We’re an all-volunteer organizaon aside from
our web development contractor. We ran a fund-drive in 2014 and
connue accepng donaons toward our launch.
Since our rst public announcements in 2013, weve aracted hun-
dreds of test users and dozens of volunteers, but we face the same chal-
lenges as other projects we aim to support. Our published wrings and
research are interesng, but the real value will come with reaching a
working beta stage.
86
Project Name: Resonate
Completed by: Peter Harris
Locaon: Berlin, Germany
URL: resonate.is
Resonate is building a streaming music plaorm with a truly unique lis-
tening model—“stream to own—which helps casual listeners become
dedicated fans. This plaorm in turn allows us to do something that
no other service can claim to do: pay musicians directly for every
single stream. The rst stream of a parcular song starts out really
cheap, while repeat plays gradually increase in price unl reaching the
normal price of a regular download.
Resonate is a mul-stakeholder cooperave where musicians,
fans, and sta share in prots and governance roles. For vong proce-
dures, its a one-member-one-vote structure, while prots are distrib-
uted according to the value generated by parcipants—various values
being the amount of streams among musicians, the expenditures of
listeners, and the me commitments of sta and volunteers.
Development has started in a number of areas: design, market
research, and technology. While signicant progress has been made,
we won’t be able to meaningfully sink into development unl we suc-
ceed in raising funds. Given the typical investor problem for all plaorm
co-ops, we’re going to seek our inial capital through crowdfunding
in parcular, by reaching out through all the musicians and indie labels
in our network. We plan to make the enre campaign reect our values
by recruing musicians and listeners to fully parcipate in geng the
word out, and by rewarding volunteers through a points system that
may be redeemed in the future for streams or exclusive content.
We’re very proud of what has been accomplished so far. Design
and branding have been rmly established (while the site connues to
evolve), and numerous content items have been wrien and shared
socially as our Twier followers and newsleer subscripons con-
nue to grow. Addionally, signicant connecons have been made
with mulpliers wring on streaming royalty issues: hundreds of
indie musicians and a few labels have joined, and we have recruited
numerous sta and volunteers eager to dive into development!
87
Project Name: Loconomics Cooperave
Completed by: Joshua Danielson
Locaon: San Francisco, California
URL: loconomics.com
Loconomics Cooperave is an on-demand web and mobile app struc-
tured as a plaorm cooperave where the owners are local service
professionals who use technology to connect to a community market-
place to grow their businesses.
Owners pay a $30 monthly user fee that funds the business team
who market and operate the plaorm. Business team employees
are also owners and will eventually be paid market-rate salaries.
Execuves will have their salaries capped at 3.5 mes the median
income of San Francisco. This ensures that income is used to further
develop and market the plaorm in the best interests of the coop-
erave. Loconomics will aim to acvely counteract the tendency for
power to be concentrated at the top by creang an equal opportunity
for owners to parcipate in governance, empowering all owners to
inuence the acvies and choices of the organizaon, and integrang
the wisdom, needs, and ideas of a broad spectrum of its owners into
the cooperave.
We’ve bootstrapped the money needed to create the inial app
with reliance from a number of professionals who, along with the
founders, will be paid with loan payments over the next ten years.
There are no equity investors, and the owner-user fees will be able
to cover these payments easily when we reach a couple of thousand
owners.
We’re just nishing beta tesng the plaorm with a small group
of owners before an ocial launch in May 2016. We had one event
in November with about twenty-ve local service professionals who
were very excited about shaping the future of the plaorm. Most felt
that a $30 monthly fee to access the plaorms benets is a small price
to pay. We have a database of a few hundred potenal local service
professional owners and just as many potenal clients.
88
Project Name: NYC Real Estate Investment Cooperave
Completed by: members of the NYC Real Estate Investment Cooperave
Locaon: New York City
URL: nycreic.com
The New York City Real Estate Investment Cooperave (NYC REIC)
is a democrac nancial organizaon that exists to secure perma-
nently aordable space for civic, small business, and cultural use.
Consistent with the principles and spirit of the cooperave
movement, the NYC REIC aims to make long-term, stabilizing, and
transformave investments for the benet of our member-owners
and our communies. We will: assist communies in raising the cap-
ital they need; work with community-based organizaons to plan
and implement their real estate development projects; and sup-
port local community acvism to ensure that the city emphasizes
aordable, community-controlled commercial space in its land use
decisions.
While member investments are the heart of the cooperave,
during the startup phase of the NYC REIC, charitable contribuons
support operang expenses. Once we have idened a few potenal
investment projects and properes, we are commied to engaging
with residents and community-based organizaons from the neigh-
borhoods where those properes are located.
We have been working together since May 2015. In just one year,
we have organized 350 members into seven acve working groups that
have met over 150 mes, raised $1.3 million in investment pledges,
and democracally elected our rst steering commiee. We have sup-
port from 596 Acres, Fourth Arts Block, Spaceworks, Brooklyn Law
School, and Fordham School of Law, and are in touch with groups that
have been inspired by us in six cies naonally. Our public meengs
have over seven hundred RSVPs, and we regularly reach capacity. We
know that this is at least a ten-year project. We know that we cannot
have the city we want without informed, acve residents. By building
a cooperave, we are educang, empowering, and shaping a powerful
group of New Yorkers who say: development without displacement is
possible.
89
Project Name: Robin Hood Collecve
Completed by: Akseli Virtanen
Locaon: Helsinki, Finland, and San Francisco, California
URL: robinhoodcoop.org
We oer distributed capital services, personal hedge funds, next-gen-
eraon opon structures, and a range of powerful nance tools for
everyone. Our moo: the king’s opons for all. We think that nance
is a place of creaon. More precisely, we build nancial tools for the
socially networked generaon—for new economic agents, doers,
makers, co-creators, and peers, who are also oen collecve, and
don’t have access to nancial tools or knowledge. We also explore
the polical and organizaonal potenal of nance, derivaves, and
securizaon.
We have dierent forms: a cooperave that is owned by its mem-
bers (Robin Hood Asset Management Cooperave); a startup owned
by the core team and its partners, who have commied to its special
purpose of building a next-generaon nance plaorm (Robin Hood
Services); and an open-source plaorm for distributed nancial tools,
owned by all of its users (Robin Hood Unlimited). This is a dynamic
organizaonal formaon that is never exhausted in its actual forms.
You can’t own a multude.
We started with the cooperave but understood that it was an
organizaonal form that belonged to the last century, to an industrial
understanding of sharing of risks and rewards. We needed a more
dynamic, more muldimensional, more distributed way of owning,
nancing, doing things together, and risking together. More equity,
more opons, more assemblage, more kings deer for all—that is what
we are building now. Blockchain technology oers the perfect organi-
zaonal infrastructure for that.
We will launch the world’s rst hedge fund on the blockchain this
spring, and the next new nancial services—DotCom Mutual Unicorn,
HouseHold Union. and DistributedCapital—later in 2016. What makes
us most proud? What we do touches people’s imaginaon.
90
Project Name: Seed.Coop
Completed by: Rylan Peery
Locaon: Ithaca, New York
URL: seed.coop
Seed.Coop helps organizaons grow by providing tools and support
services for easy onboarding of new members.
Seed.Coop is currently held in trust by CoLab Cooperave and will
be structured in a way that meaningfully gives control and ownership
to a diverse set of cooperave members and stakeholders (see hp://
bit.ly/colab_in_trust for a full explanaon).
The prototype of the plaorm has been built via sweat equity by
core team members. CoLab Coop has provided sponsorship funds to
underwrite a percentage of the development. The steering team is
currently exploring outside funding sources and pilot organizaons to
accelerate development of the plaorm. Of parcular importance is
cooperave support among organizaons so that there are no silos
between orgs building membership. Instead, members share a symbi-
oc relaonship via a member “referral engine.”
We have built our rst prototype of the plaorm and are now
working on prototyping decentralized membership onboarding solu-
ons for specic partners. We expect that, in 2017, Seed.Coop will
be a cooperavely owned plaorm for member onboarding working
interoperably with plaorms like Coopify and The Working World.
91
14. THE REALISM OF
COOPERATIVISM
YOCHAI BENKLER
Cooperativism, or mutualism, has been in the repertoire of alterna-
tives to capitalism since nineteenth-century gures like Owen and
Proudhon. In some regions—the Basque Country, or Emilia-Romagna
in Italy—or industriesU.S. dairy farming, for instancecoopera-
tives have become major, sustainable parts of the region or sector. But
we have to be honest: cooperativism has not played a transformational
role in the past two centuries of capitalism.
Four dimensions of opportunity suggest that the future could be
dierent.
First, disruption. Things are very much up in the air. Uber is
growing dominant in personal-transportation services in the United
States, but Uber could still be the Friendster, or at most the LinkedIn,
of the on-demand economy if the cooperative movement moves fast
into a broad range of services. Historically, cooperatives have been
stable in the face of market competition where they did emerge, but
not suciently competitive to force their way into markets already
saturated by conventional rms. Conventions, imitation, and prac-
tice—not economic superioritydetermined the presence or absence
of cooperatives. The moment of opportunity is now, when the organ-
ization of production is still in ux.
Second, we are in the cultural moment of cooperation. Wikipedia,
free and open-source software (FOSS), citizen journalism, and other
forms of commons-based peer production have made normal people
encounter cooperation and its products as a matter of everyday
92
practice. The decades-long insistence of expert economics that we
should think of ourselves as self-interested rational actors acting with
guile is bumping up against a daily reality that refutes it. Sciences,
from evolutionary biology through the social sciences, psychology, and
neuroscience, are all lining up to conrm that people are not the moral
midgets and sociopaths that populate game theory and rational actor
modeling—that many of us cooperate when we are in situations we
understand as cooperative, and compete when we are in situations that
we feel are competitive.
Practice and theory are providing the cultural framework within
which people can come to believe that cooperativism can in fact work,
on a mass scale, for important swaths of their Internet-mediated social
practice.
Third, commons-based peer production has provided a template
and experience with the possibility of large-scale enterprises managing
and governing themselves through online cooperative platforms. They
oer extensive and growing experience with how networked peers
govern themselves, allocate work and responsibility, and manage day-
to-day operations across time and space. Peer cooperativism shares these
core governance and organizational patterns with commons-based
peer production, but its dening feature, enabling workers to make
a living from their cooperative work, presents distinct challenges that
peer production has not had to face.
Finally, networks have destabilized the model of the rm.
Transaction costs associated with both market exchanges and social
sharing have declined; interactions once preserved for rms that com-
bined capital with contractual commitments for labor, materials, and
distribution can now be done in a more distributed form. This tech-
nological fact has underwritten the rise of the on-demand economy,
workforce management software that increases contingency, and out-
sourcing and oshoring no less than it underwrote FOSS, Wikipedia,
or SETI@home. It will not determine a more cooperative future,
but it does mitigate some of the most important barriers that histor-
ically hampered cooperativism. Uber and Airbnb both involve the
93
reallocation, through markets, of shareable goods: mid-grained lumpy
goods, put in service by people for their own use, but with excess
capacity. When those who enthuse about these platforms emphasize
that they have built the largest transportation or hospitality company
without building a single room or owning a single vehicle, they are
meanwhile pointing out that the barrier to eective scale for cooper-
ativesthe need to invest concentrated capital—is less strictly con-
straining than it once was. Commons-based peer production has
shown us that software can be developed as FOSS, marketing can be
done peer-to-peer, and it is likely that the legal and political meaning
and contests over services will be fundamentally more legitimate and
less oppositional when the service is built by cooperating peers.
The combination of economic disruption and the opportunities to
capture new markets, a shared cultural imagination of the possibilities
of cooperation, and deep practical experience with online cooperation
as a practical solution space make this moment dierent than it might
have been two decades ago, much less in the heyday of industrial cap-
italism. Maybe.
There are real challenges before peer cooperativism can occupy
a substantial space in the networked economy. Peer production has
thrived on pooling voluntary contributions of participants who had
other means of making a living. This allowed commons-based peer
production to release its outputs mostly free of charge, as well as
free as in freedom.” Peer cooperativism, if it is to become part of
the solution to the increased economic insecurity for the many in
the twenty-rst century, must be able to sustain cooperation while
charging customers and users a price and fairly distributing the pro-
ceeds among the peers. This is a challenge that commons-based peer
production did not face. The established cooperative movement has
shown that the challenge is not insurmountable, but it is real. Not least
among these challenges will be the need to mediate the driving ethic
of peer production, ensuring that its outputs are in the commons and
available for all, with the necessity of providing income to the peers
themselves. This will be easier for service models, as we have seen
94
with FOSS, than for information goods that do not have a clear service
model, like stock photography. Ethical coherence strongly suggests
that cooperatives providing information goods must develop models
of shared membership or service, rather than aim for building on an
intellectual property” strategy that will separate these cooperatives
from the heart of the movement.
Cooperativism is not simply shared ownership, as are many
employee-ownership plans. It is, rst and foremost, shared govern-
ance. Oscar Wilde is supposed to have said “the trouble with socialism
is that it cuts into your evenings”; the labor involved in peer cooper-
ativism presents a challenge, although online democratic governance
platforms oer exibility, transparency, tracking, and discourse-ow
aordances that can make the load more manageable than it was for
physical world cooperatives. Some FOSS projects, like Debian, have
successfully developed a democratic process. Many others depend on
a charismatic-leadership model that may not translate well into the
domain of making a livelihood. The primary resource for platform
cooperativists must be the rich literature on commons governance
pioneered by Elinor Ostrom, which did in fact focus on collaborative
communities managing their livelihood resources together without
property rights or government laws. The growing work on gov-
erning knowledge commons is the best source of translating between
the Ostrom school and the experiences of online cooperation, albeit
without the focus on making money and distributing it.
The enormous literature on governance in Wikipedia will be
pertinent, for instance, because Wikipedia, unlike many other peer
production communities, has evolved into a body that has a respon-
sibility—cultural, if not economic—for an output. And Wikipedia
tells us that things won’t be easy. Combining lessons from the rich
literature on Wikipedia governance with the Ostrom-school litera-
ture must drive cooperatives to design not only participation, but also
mutual monitoring and dispute resolution systems, and in particular
aordances to permit nested power or subsidiarity—the organization
of governance at the closest possible level to where the activity being
95
governed is taking place, while coordinating across the cooperative.
The biggest likely divergence from peer production will be the need
to define membership more strictly. In cooperativism, as with
commons-property-regimes, it will be important to clearly dene
who members are, and place a higher barrier on membership than peer
production has done. This is so partly because the quality and timing
of outputs will be more critical, and partly because of the need to
maintain a reasonably dened universe of participants among whom
returns suciently high to make a real contribution to their livelihood
must be shared.
Decades of studies of cooperation tell us that communication
among members—particularly communication that humanizes mem-
bers to each other—is central, as is developing a shared identity. A
strong core of moral values, avoidance of an ethic of “I’m just here for
the extra few bucks,” and a clear commitment to fairness among the
members will be necessary to overcome the inevitable tensions associ-
ated with work and income sharing. Framing is important, and while
self-interest undoubtedly plays a role in any community, no eort that
appeals primarily to that self-interest will likely survive, let alone out-
perform explicitly self-interested models of investor-owned rms.
At no time in the two centuries since cooperativism rst appeared
as a conscious alternative model to modern organization of produc-
tion has it been more feasible. That it is feasible, however, does not
make it inevitable. As a movement, cooperativism will only succeed
by moving fast and decisively, learning from the near past, and sharing
our experiments and knowledge quickly and repeatedly in a network
of cooperatives.
96
15. THREE ESSENTIAL
BUILDING BLOCKS FOR YOUR
PLATFORM COOPERATIVE
JANELLE ORSI
Below, I describe three elements I believe should be encoded securely
into the legal structures of platform cooperatives. These are particu-
larly designed for cooperatives that aim to be of long-term benet to
their members.
Oh, wait. Sorry about my redundant sentence. I basically just said
that these elements are for cooperatives that aim to be cooperatives. That
is the purpose of cooperatives: to benet their members.
I had to start with that reminder because I think it’s hard for most
of us, having embedded ourselves into the dominant models of doing
business, to break away from certain notions about what a tech startup
should do and how it should work. It’s enormously challenging to
narrow in, with unclouded and unwavering focus, on just one thing:
to be of benet to a community of platform users.
I frequently hear people talk about cooperatives as if they are a
plugin that can be installed into a run-of-the mill corporate struc-
ture. But cooperatives are a completely dierent operating system.
They process things quite dierently, and their outputs are dif-
ferent. In a world where the dominant models of doing business
are widely recognized to be escalating inequality and destroying
the planet, we desperately need to build economic operating sys-
tems that achieve the exact opposite. Cooperatives can be such
an operating system if we build them with great care, adapt them
97
constantly, and install every possible protection from infection by
business-as-usual.
When I started practicing law eight years ago, I committed to
focusing my work on supporting cooperatives. I’ve now seen both suc-
cesses and failures among cooperatives, and I’m perpetually challenged
by questions like what makes cooperatives work and endure, and how
can they manifest true economic democracy? Of course, these ques-
tions merit multiple volumes. For now, I’ll share three things that I
would advise any platform cooperative to build into its legal structure.
Before I dive in, though, here are a few concepts that guide my
thinking on platform cooperatives:
First, platforms are us: Platforms aren’t just software applica-
tions and the companies that administer them. What gives a platform
value, in most cases, is the community of users that employ the plat-
form, along with the networks, data, and ideas they create. In other
words, what makes platforms so valuable is what we put into them.
Second, platforms don’t need to be treated as commodi-
ties: It’s easy to develop a platform fetish as a result of their seemingly
magical potential to create billionaires. Yet all along, it is the users
themselves, and the rents they pay to platform companies, that enable
the billion-dollar valuations. Cooperatives, however, exist to provide
benet to their members, and they do so by not charging rents to begin
with. It would make no sense for a cooperative to charge excessive fees
to users—it would just end up paying the fees back to the same users
in dividends later.
When the spell of the platform fetish has been broken, we can
go back to focusing on the primordial function of platforms: bene-
ting users. Maintaining this focus wont be easy—not when we are
pulled back into business-as-usual thought patterns nearly every time
we interact in the world. This will get easier the more that we come to
be surrounded by other cooperatives. Less and less, we’ll nd ourselves
asking things like: How can we market to a wealthier class? How can
we raise prices? More and more, we’ll ask things like: What else can
we do to help our users? How can we lower prices? It sounds strange
98
at rst, but transitions like this can make us wake up every morning
feeling slightly more grounded and human than the day before.
In the meantime, we can install strong protections that defend
our cooperatives from even our own habitual ways of thinking.
Fortunately, cooperatives come with at least two pre-installed protec-
tions, which are built into cooperative legal structures: First, money
doesn’t buy power in a cooperative; cooperative members elect the
Board of Directors on a one-member one-vote basis. Second, money
doesn’t buy prots in a cooperative; cooperative members may receive
dividends, but the dividends are calculated in direct proportion to
money spent by or earned by each member, not on the basis of how
much money anyone had the privilege to invest. These are powerful
protections in a world where money seems to buy power and prots
everywhere else.
Beyond those pre-installed protections, I’d urge that a few other
principles be embedded into cooperative bylaws and policies. Here are
my three big building blocks:
1. Prevent the platform from being sold. Imagine that your
platform cooperative builds a vibrant community of ten thousand
dedicated member-users. Then a large company or investor comes
along and oers your cooperative $50 million to take over ownership.
Tempting, right? Each member could get a payout averaging $5,000.
But the potential for quick cash can blind people to their long-term
self-interest. A for-prot company could start charging higher fees to
users, selling their data, manipulating search algorithms to privilege
some users over others, and other practices that put users at a perma-
nent disadvantage in relation to the company.
It is critical to adopt strong safeguards against the potential for
the platform and any of its major assets to be sold into for-prot struc-
tures. A decision to sell major assets of the platform should require a
high threshold of approval, such as by 80 percent of members, after
what would hopefully be a long public conversation about alterna-
tives. I would even suggest that outside parties, such as a panel of non-
prots and other cooperatives, be given the opportunity to review
99
any proposed sale, veto it, or exercise a right of rst refusal to buy the
assets. Lastly, to remove a major incentive to sell to a company, I rec-
ommend capping the amount of sale proceeds that can go to members
and sending the rest to a nonprot.
2. Put a cap on pay-outs and compensation. In our competi-
tion-driven economy, a scarcity mentality has given many peopleor
even most—an insatiable drive to accumulate wealth. Even a coop-
erative can get swept up in this dynamic if powerful stakeholders use
their leverage to extract value from the cooperative. Executives could
vie for higher and higher pay. Although cooperatives generallyand
preferably—do not allow for prot-maximizing equity investment, a
cooperative could still end up giving up too much to lenders or pre-
ferred shareholders. To prevent these possibilities from even making it
to the negotiation table, a cooperative’s bylaws should establish caps on
employee pay, investment return, and other payouts.
Where to set those caps? The platform cooperative Loconomics
uses data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics to cap employee pay at
3.5 times the median wage for all occupations in the region where the
employee works. In the Bay Area, the cap would be $165,000. Among
tech CEOs, that might sound like poverty. But to an average person,
that might sound like, well, a whole 3.5 times better than life as it
is. It’s all relative, and the notion of “enough” is completely lost in a
society with such dramatic income inequality.
When decisions are no longer driven by the desire to maximize
gain, I think that a desire to ensure that everyone has enough is the
ethic that steps in to replace it. True, a company wont be able to attract
the kind of talent that thinks of everything in terms of commodities
and maximizing monetary prot. But it will attract talented people
who are smart enough and have enough self-awareness to know that
doing good work with good people is what makes for a good life.
If you hire someone who is driven not by prot-maximization, but
rather by a desire to do meaningful work, they will also be more intu-
itively oriented to the cooperative’s purpose of beneting members.
Which leads me to the third item…
100
3. Adopt a sta trusteeship model of governance. Sta trus-
teeship is a governance model that views all sta members of the coop-
erative as trustees who manage the platform for its beneciaries, the
body of members as a whole. I believe that sta trusteeship is a natural
model for large cooperatives in particular. Democracy in larger coop-
eratives is often quite bare-bones, mostly limited to members voting
for directors. Members’ voices are easily lost if they are primarily
expressed through the election of a board that meets infrequently and
is not very tuned in to the day-to-day work.
In a sta trusteeship cooperative, every sta person becomes a
point of accountability for the organization, taking on responsibility to
listen to and amplify the voices of its members. Sta self-manage using
an internal governance and operational model such as Holacracy or
sociocracy, which distribute power among sta, removing inecient
hierarchies and ensuring a great deal of agency for each sta member.
In a sta trusteeship cooperative, the board of directors is still
elected, but it takes on a role that is more akin to that of a guardian,
overseeing the activities of the organization and ensuring that the sta
are tuning in to members in every possible way. Incidentally, sta will
generally nd their work far more interesting and rewarding in this
model. They are not there to merely execute the directives of a board
or CEO; they get to bring their full selves to work, to apply their
talents, engage their full potential, and work with members to solve
real-life problems.
The list of things I would build into cooperative bylaws is actually
much longer than the above, but I have emphasized just three here,
because I nd them particularly useful in jolting us out of business-
as-usual ways of thinking, and in getting us back to the pure focus on
being humans working to benet humans.
By the way, you can replace the word “platform” in this article
with “housing,” “land,” “workplace,” “water,” “food,” or “energy,
and apply the same principles to any cooperative. The beauty of
platforms, however, is that they are far easier to cooperativize than,
say, land and housing. Platforms are us. We don’t need to mobilize
101
enormous amounts of capital to build a cooperative economy in the
world of tech. We primarily need to mobilize ourselves to make dif-
ferent choices. Then, having done that, we will have built collective
power, which gives us a platform of a dierent sort: one on which to
launch cooperatives of all varieties to take back land, housing, water,
energy, jobs, food, and everything else that has been poorly served by
business-as-usual.
102
16. SO YOU WANT TO START
A PLATFORM COOPERATIVE
CAROLINE WOOLARD
Dear Founder,
I’m glad to hear about your idea for a cooperative platform.
Congratulations! I’m sure we both agree that a diversity of opinions
is a good thing, and that platforms should benet their participants,
as participation is what makes a platform valuable. What follows are a
few questions that I wish someone had asked me when I started four
multi-year projects, most of which continue to run today.
The projects I co-founded, for what it’s worth, are an
8,000-square-foot aordable studio space (Splinters and Logs LLC,
2008–2016), a resource-sharing network (OurGoods.org, 2016
present), an international learning platform that runs on barter
(TradeSchool.coop, 2010present), and an advocacy group for
cultural equity (BFAMFAPhD.com, 2014present). I also helped
convene the rst gatherings of the NYC Real Estate Investment
Cooperative in 2015 with Risa Shoup and Paula Segal, and am
inspired by the ongoing work of the NYC REIC’s member-elected
steering committee and the open working groups.
I am sharing these four questions, along with bits of advice,
because I hope that you will succeed in contributing toward the
cooperative culture we want to see. To live in a democratic society,
we all need more experiences of democracy at work, in school, and
at home. Thank you for helping push the cooperative movement
forward.
103
You will notice that a lot of what follows also speaks to founders
of nonprot organizations or social impact businesses. I am writing
this especially for young, educationally privileged people who
have big ideas but are newcomers to the neighborhood they live
in. This reects my own experience as a college graduate, waking
up to working class histories in New York City while trying to
build cooperative software and resource-sharing projects. It took
me a while to learn outside my immediate group of friends; to reach
beyond the academy and beyond the Internet to learn.
1. Can you make a platform for an existing co-op?
In a culture that values ideas over practices, it might be hard
to see the existing cooperatives around you. But, I promise you,
there are many systems of mutual aid and cooperation nearby. These
“platforms” are systems of self-determination and survival created
by people who have been systematically denied resources through
institutionalized racism, sexism, and classism (read about redlining if
you don’t know what that is). The credit unions, land trusts, work-
er-owned businesses, rotating lending clubs (susus), community gar-
dens, and freedom schools in your neighborhood may not have great
websites, but they are incredible cooperative platforms that you can
learn from and with.
These initiatives are often not lifestyle choices made by educa-
tionally privileged people, and will therefore not be written up in The
New York Times, but they are robust and powerful community networks
with organizers who might be interested in adding an online platform to
their work. Here is an often-overlooked challenge: try to join and add
to existing cooperative platforms, rather than building your own from
scratch. The result will likely last longer as it will be informed by the
deep wisdom of existing cooperative community norms, roles, and rules.
Perhaps we need something like the Center for Urban Pedagogy for
cooperative softwarean organization that matches grassroots groups
with developers to build software that is driven by community need.
104
2. Who will build the cooperative platform?
Let’s say that organizers at your local credit union, land trust,
cooperative developer, community garden, or freedom school are
interested in building an online cooperative platform to add to their
ongoing work. Or, they conrm your hunch that the cooperative plat-
form you want to build is necessary. How will you form a team that
can make this software come to life?
I have found that innovation occurs most readily in small teams
with shared goals but dierent skill sets. Big groups, on the other
hand, are good for education and organizing work, and for rening
existing platforms. But to innovate, I like to work in core teams
of three to six people, as this allows for deep relationships, shared
memory, and relatively fast decision making, since each person can
speak for ten to twenty minutes per hour in meetings. The collec-
tive Temporary Services says that every person you add to the group
doubles the amount of time it takes to make a decision. So, I say:
build a small group of rigorous, generous experts whose past work
demonstrates that they are aligned with the cooperative platform
you want to make. Ask the larger group to consent to the expertise
of your small team, and ensure that your small team will make room
for feedback from the big group along the way.
Now, build your team! Find people who are better than you in
their area of expertise. At the very least, you will need: 1) a Project
Manager to help with scheduling events, facilitating meetings, and
tracking budgets; 2) a Communications Pro to craft a clear message
and recruit people to try out the platform as it develops; 3) a Designer
(or two) who makes the front end beautiful, 4) a Developer (or two)
who develops the software and annotates it so that other people can
add to it in the future; and 5) Advisors—one per area of expertise
above, as well as more who have strong connections to the community
you aim to work with. Meet with your core team on a weekly, if not
daily basis, and with your advisors on a monthly or quarterly basis.
105
You are likely the Communications Pro or the Project Manager,
since you are reading this letter. Find advisors who are retired, or far
older than you, and who have seen the eld change and are widely
respected for their work. Learn about programming languages
which languages (Ruby, Python, etc.) have active development com-
munities, and which languages are most likely to be interoperable with
future cooperative platforms. Find developers who have worked on
social justice projects in the past. If you are a nonprot with limited
funds, watch out for developers who want to get paid market rate, as
developers and project managers (like you) should believe in the pro-
ject equally and should take an equal pay cut. Watch out for developers
who say they can build the site in a public hackathon or sprint, because
if they do that it won’t be built well.
3. How much time and money do you have?
As you build your team, be honest with yourself about your
existing priorities, and the likelihood that your life will change in the
coming months or year or two. To gauge our availability to work on
TradeSchool.coop, we did an exercise where each core member wrote
a list of their top life priorities, including family, friends, health, vol-
unteer projects, art, hobbies, and day jobs. This allowed us to be more
honest with ourselves and each other about the amount of time we had
to work on our project, which parts of our life were unknown, and
also our reasons for doing the project.
Plan for turnover by having clear systems of documentation and
open conversations about how to bring in people who might join the
core team when someone has to leave. Be sure that the Developer(s)
code in teams, or that an Advisor looks over the code, so that it is
intelligible to your other Developers. Be sure that the Project Manager
and Communications Pro share leadership and responsibility, crafting
a clear process for new people to join the core team, moving from roles
of assistance to core membership in months. After a year of organizing
TradeSchool.coop, I wrote a manual to make sure our systems were
106
clear. Ask yourself: do you want to get it done, or do you want to get
it done your way? This is the question that Jen Abrams, a co-founder
of OurGoods.org, brought to us from a decade at the collectively run
performance space WOW Café Theater.
4. What if you ran events and hired a community organizer
instead of building software?
Last of all, consider the possibility that you could make a greater
impact on cooperative culture and resource-sharing in your commu-
nity by hosting events rather than building a new cooperative plat-
form online. Software does not run itself; it must be maintained and
upgraded by developers who can easily make tons of money working
on non-cooperative platforms.
Remember that people won’t take the time to learn a new app
unless they need it daily. Remember that people are used to Facebook,
Google, Twitter, and sites that have legions of developers working
around the clock. Remember that hire number three at Airbnb was a
lobbyist. If you are starting out, build the smallest feature and do not
add to it. It will be hard enough to maintain and upgrade that small
feature.
Be honest about your ability to put in long hours and to raise the
funds to sustain the development and constant upgrading of online
networks for years. Until we have cooperative investment platforms
for cooperative ventures, you will have to look for philanthropic sup-
port or venture capital that might alter your mission and that will
rarely sustain the initiative for years.
If you can’t raise $300,000 a year for a core team of ve, don’t
build a demo site that barely works or buggy software that wont last—
organize great events and build community! You can use existing
online platforms that your members already know. You can use your
funds to pay a community organizer instead. Not only will you sustain
the livelihood of a wonderful person, but the knowledge built in the
107
community won’t return a 404 Server Error when someone needs help
next year.
In cooperation,
Caroline Woolard
PS: If you want more information, just email me at carolinewoolard
@gmail.com. I also put a lot of links to organizing, facilitating, and
horizontal structures in the How to Start a Trade School manual from 2012,
and the NYC Real Estate Investment Cooperatives REIC U working
group is making a long list as well. Look for it on NYCREIC.org!
108
17. WHAT WE MEAN WHEN
WE SAY “COOPERATIVE
MELISSA HOOVER
Is platform cooperativism a social movement or a market intervention?
I would argue it is both, but that we should clarify the distinct implica-
tions of each of those imperatives—how they could come into conict
with one another, and where they can intersect powerfully.
These questions—these tensions, and their power—are not unique
to platform cooperatives. They animate the cooperative form at its
core, as cooperatives sit squarely at the intersection of values and mar-
kets, organizing and business, community institution and economic
engine. Understanding this nexus with as much clarity as possible will
help us build successful platform cooperatives and the appropriate eco-
systems of support for them.
As we advance our thinking on platform cooperatives, there seems
to be some impulse to muddy the concept of cooperatives, even to
dilute it so thoroughly that it comes to mean “something we like,” or
“something based on values,” or “something not owned by outside
shareholders.” All of these are partially true, but none captures the
promise of the form completely. It is critically important not to dilute
the meaning of “cooperative” as we advocate for it on a broader scale.
Rather, we should let the concept’s clarity move us toward simpler
and clearer formulations of what we mean when we say “platform
cooperativism.
At their most basic, cooperatives are values-based businesses
that operate for member benet, that are owned and controlled by
the people who do business within them. They are formed to meet
109
those members’ needs, and the nature of the members’ economic rela-
tionship to the cooperative determines what kind of cooperative it
is. Though centered on member and community benet, coopera-
tives are not nonprots; they operate in the market and are subject to
market forces, although they often arise where conventional markets
have failed to meet people’s needs.
Carrots can help us understand some of the types of cooperatives:
If the members’ need is to buy carrots, they may form a coop-
erative that buys carrots in bulk and sells them to members.
This is a consumer cooperative: the members are con-
sumers, and the cooperative helps them access products at a
fair price.
If the members are carrot farmers and their need is to sell their
carrots, they may form a cooperative that pools their car-
rots, sells them under a shared brand, and gets the best price
they can in the market. This is a producer (or marketing)
cooperative: the members are independent producers and
the cooperative helps them access markets to sell products at
a fair price.
If the members’ need is for paid work, they may form a carrot
processing plant that buys carrots, adds value through their
labor, sells the carrots, and uses the income to pay members.
This is a worker cooperative: the members are workers and
the cooperative helps them access good jobs.
If a cooperative is designed to meet multiple types of needs,
it may have multiple types of members. This is a multi-
stakeholder cooperative: carrot growers connect to carrot
distributors and carrot consumers in one holistic entity that
aggregates all three pools of membership.
Amazon, of course, isn’t selling carrots; it’s selling convenience
and logistics. Uber isn’t a taxi company; it’s a lobbyist, a loan shark,
a labor broker. Developing platform cooperativism past its infancy
110
stageor more to the point, intervening in platform capitalism as it
reaches the terrible twos—requires a keen ability to discern what is
really being sold, how the money actually ows, and who benets. A
return to the fundamental questions that structure cooperatives—who
are the members, what is their relationship to the cooperative, and
how is it meeting their needs?—can sharpen our analysis, bring much-
needed clarity to a complex concept, and help identify eective inter-
ventions that center on worker and community benet.
Workers’ needs clearly are not being met by current platforms.
Platform capitalism removes any accountable mediator between capital
and labor: there is no management to petition, no corporate structure
to organize against, just the platform with its built-in discipline of
user ratings and a contingent labor pool fathoms deep. Meet the new
boss, same as the old boss—except without, you know, any actual boss,
just the unmitigated imperative of capital to return value to investors.
Cooperatives actually connect investors directly to markets, too, but
in a very dierent way: the investors are members of the coopera-
tive itself. This alignment of interests can capture the promise of the
platform—direct connection to distributed markets—while centering
worker benet as its reason for being.
In the context of the platform economy, the old distinctions among
types of cooperatives still matter immensely. Why? The relationship
between owners and employers remains at the heart of many platform
capitalism models, although the platform owners attempt to turn our
attention away from it. Cooperative forms inherit this challenge; they
don’t automatically solve it. Neither platforms nor cooperatives are
so revolutionary that they obviate the need to address workers’ rights
and protections. A platformeven when owned cooperatively—is still
simply brokering market access and labor relations. For these arrange-
ments to be fair, they need to be clear.
Platform co-op developers should think carefully about what kind
of cooperative they intend to create. For instance, there may be good
reasons to set up a platform cooperative of producers, rather than one
based in an employment relationship. Taxi drivers may want to retain
111
autonomy over their earnings and exibility of gigs; house cleaners
may want to maintain a direct economic relationship with a client;
both may want a platform to increase their access to a market. Owning
and controlling the platform as a cooperative of independent operators
ensures that it serves them, rather than extracting from them. For con-
sumers, producer platform cooperatives may oer greater variety or
availability of service providers, while uniting them under a common
brand that conveys trust or increases access.
Similarly, there are reasons to set up a platform worker cooper-
ative. Care workers and their clients may want the protections that
come from a client-facing employer entity; owning and controlling
the platform as an employment entity provides both the protections
of employment and the workers’ right to set the terms for a market
they rely on. For consumers, the accountability and reassurance
oered by an employer entity may be critical; people may be reluc-
tant to entrust their aging parents’ in-home care to a stranger from
the Internet, and only an institutional relationship can appropriately
mitigate that risk.
In any of these cases, membership is meaningful, equating to
ownership and control over the entity. A platform that doesn’t actu-
ally consider at a granular level the question of membership, its mem-
bers’ needs, and their relationship to the cooperativeone that uses
cooperative” as some sort of trust mark not backed by actual coop-
erative structures—runs the risk of simply being part of the problem.
Marketing the brand without the structure could end up replicating
and reinforcing contingency and, more practically, resting on a very
shaky foundation as a business.
Millions of dollars of venture capital are pouring into platforms
designed to exploit our desire for convenience while destabilizing
entire workforcesand often still not achieving market viability. The
advantages of this platform capitalism, meanwhile, are being aggres-
sively marketed and consolidated. We must therefore be especially clear
about the added value of the “cooperative” in platform cooperativism.
Platform cooperatives will be worthy of consumer trust only because
112
they are structurally built on trust: members operating a business for
member and community benet.
In the platform context, the added value of cooperatives comes
from the democratic commitments that they operate around—and
clarity of purpose is necessary to build structures that operate in ser-
vice of those commitments. As we react to rapidly changing economic
and social structures, we can best retool our principles and our strategy
for this new world by keeping clear focus on some decidedly old-world
cooperative fundamentals.
113
18. A DIFFERENT KIND OF
STARTUP IS POSSIBLE
DAVID CARROLL
The standard template for creating a tech company has begun to crack.
In 2016, investors are funding fewer companies than before, and many
of those that have been funded are announcing layos as their exu-
berant valuations are adjusted to worsening market conditions. For
founders, it’s becoming increasingly dicult to raise new or subse-
quent rounds of funding, as investors regain leverage over the entre-
preneurs who have put their livelihoods, careers, and emotional well-
being on the line to pursue their big ideas.
Two years ago, after working on a sponsored research project with
my graduate students at Parsons, we decided to spin o our machine-
learning publishing platform into a tech startup. We worked according
to the only model we knew, where you sell your equity to investors
on a massive bet that you can become their mythical unicorn success
story. Like the 90 percent of new companies that you never hear about
because they fail, we didn’t win the startup lottery. While our business
didn’t succeed, we learned lessons about starting a technology com-
pany. We also noticed ways in which the landscape is already starting
to shift as new technology radically transforms and disrupts markets
and opportunities, yet again.
Today, I’m a recovering entrepreneur, still reeling from the side
eects of losing our bet. But if another opportunity to build another
technology platform presented itself tomorrow, we now have an
entirely new labor and ownership model to consider, given that the
co-op model is increasingly being adapted to technology platforms. In
114
many ways, the platform co-op model is well suited to counteract some
of the ownership and sustainability problems intrinsic to venture-backed
enterprises that we encountered rsthand. But near-future tech plat-
forms will be built upon rapidly evolving infrastructures and will require
sudden adaptations to new capabilities. Given technology to come, what
assumptions should be questioned? Platform co-ops need to be designed
for tomorrow’s marketplace, not today’s. Based on lessons learned from
starting a tech company, along with my academic research, I anticipate
that the following sets of challenges and opportunities will shape the
possibilities for entirely new categories of cooperative businesses.
Platform co-ops can benet from the bursting of the
content bubble. The Web suers from the dominance of can-
cerous impression-based advertising, and so new business models
for producing content are badly needed. The same pressure from
walled-garden social sharing platforms like Facebook, Instagram, and
Snapchat monopolizing app audiences also threatens the viability of
the commons and the Open Web. Its content is largely supplied by
the legacy publishing industry to be consumed by conventionally prof-
itable audiences measured by impressions using invasive industrial
surveillance technologies. As people adopt ad-blocking software on a
linear growth curve past the 200 million users of today, the traditional
publisher business model is threatened. An increasing reliance on dis-
covering content through sharing on the big platforms’ news feeds
ensues. Impression metrics continue to drive the industry to overpro-
duction, leading toward the risk of a content bubble bursting. Platform
co-ops like Member’s Media and Resonate can seize upon this desta-
bilization as we seek new models for funding and producing media for
connected audiences.
App store opportunities are drying up. At rst, app stores
were a boon to independent newcomers. Now app stores are crowded,
and the select few apps that get installed on home screens compete for
our daily attention. App makers are increasingly struggling to sur-
vive on these over-saturated storefronts. Indeed, proprietary platforms
inherently conict with the philosophy of free, open, and decentralized
115
systems and so many cooperatives might reject these corporate market-
places that take a steep cut of proceeds, arbitrarily regulate access, and
concentrate platform market-share. But can you make a big enough
impact if youre not on these devices? If you need to, how can you
earn a coveted home-screen spot or t into our communication habits?
What if you dont need to build an app, but rather should be building
a modular service that integrates into the social communications apps
that already consume our attention?
Chat is the new interface for apps. What comes after apps?
As people spend most of their time in messaging apps and less and less
time in specialized app utilities, functionalities are migrating into our
conversational interactions. We are seeing how modularized services
are poised to replace apps, where the familiar functionality of apps
dissolves into the text messaging prompt of our preferred chat service.
Amazon expects its customers to verbally chat with its shopping bot
Alexa on their Echo home appliance. Facebook has planned to oer
publishers access to its Messenger platform to deliver news as a con-
versation with users. Slack dominates the workplace communications
pipeline and pioneered integrations with other services and bots to
meet workers where they already are. Text-based labor platforms like
Jana suggest that this is possible in the context of platform co-ops.
What if you could connect and support a platform co-op through chat
bots rather than relying on your potential customers to download and
keep using your app or remembering your website?
With articial intelligence maturing quickly, it will matter
more and more who owns it. Leading computer scientists predict a
50 percent chance that software will substantially write itself by 2050.
But we’re already seeing more machine learning capabilities woven
into the fabric of our daily lives. As apps and the Open Web gradually
give way to big platforms, we’ll see more and more people converse
with machines in natural language rather than tapping icons and na-
gling user-interfaces. It’s possible that the bulk of our utilities and con-
tent consumption will be further embedded into our messaging apps
as bots bump out buttons. What does this mean for platform co-ops
116
who need to capture the attention of people, communicate with them,
and transact following the prevailing business logics, and do this eth-
ically? There is an urgent and critical need to build AI platforms that
are co-owned and governed by the people who will use them for
more and more purposes. These crucial eorts will help alternative AI
software mature and develop toward an intelligence that truly repre-
sents us, not just the wealthy few who funded the earliest research and
development expenditures.
Cooperative online platforms need a free, open, and rad-
ically decentralized answer to the cloud. The cloud is expensive
and decentralized platforms are only now emerging. Platform owners
claim that the Internet is free, but the conation of free-as-in-libre
and free-as-in-gratis causes confusion. The corporate cloud, really, is
just someone else’s computer; it is at odds with platform co-op ethics,
especially when we realize we’re just renting access and computa-
tion. However, to deliver the AI-powered features that near-future
users will demand, applications will need to draw upon sophisti-
cated industrial-strength AI software services and harness powerful
clusters of data-mining server farms. This stu doesn’t come cheap.
Free, open, and radically decentralized AI isn’t a thing yet, but
blockchain-based platforms like Ethereum and Backfeed could oer
decentralized alternatives to the corporate cloud. More libre but not
gratis, as youll pay for decentralization with cryptocurrency. In its
infancy, Ethereum is far more expensive than the Amazon cloud but
with laughable performance and capability by comparison. Can you
aord to wait for the decentralized solution or do you accept that a
corporate cloud is presently your only viable high-performance and
aordable option?
Co-ops require novel legal frameworks. Starting a conven-
tional tech startup incurs tremendous legal costs that even make the
cloud seem like a bargain. Co-ops require complex legal negotiations,
which demand specialized legal expertise. With our startup, we sunk
some of our common stock equity into our lawyer and accrued addi-
tional, deferred, unpaid legal fees to build our entity and negotiate deals.
117
And by the time we had a thick corporate book of complex invest-
ment and intellectual property agreements, we hadn’t even gotten to
writing up our privacy policy and terms of service, both of which would
have been unusually expensive because we didn’t want to simply adopt
aggressively invasive boilerplates. Without formidable legal prowess, the
business world can eat you alive, especially in software. Perhaps the most
important early innovation in platform co-ops will be free and open
legal frameworks and new attorney compensation models that eschew
the conicts of interest pioneered by Silicon Valley lawyers.
Platform co-ops can mitigate dark surveillance patterns.
Can you mitigate surveillance and dark AI patterns? Building
data-driven technology can be scary. It’s horrifying how easy it is to
build a behavior-tracking infrastructure with modern web frameworks.
Everything gets much worse when you have to extract payments from
people. The software and metrics begin to write their own behav-
ior-tracking algorithms. When AI takes over, particular attention has
to be paid to surveillance-related design elements. Unchecked, they
could pose grave dangers. Platform co-ops can succeed at building
privacy-positivity and basic decency into products and sell this as a
competitive advantage against venture capitalist-backed tech compa-
nies that lack such qualities because they practice what is increasingly
recognized as surveillance capitalism, the extraction of our data to
modify our behaviors at scale.
Learn from those who are succeeding already. Stocksy United
is winning by being a design-led co-op that serves its design-oriented
customers through co-ownership. Loconomics is gaining traction
in the micro-labor market by solving pain-points of customers that
VC-backed startups don’t even touch, such as certifying the safety cre-
dentials of service providers. Fairmondo is a platform co-op Amazon-
style retailer. But dig deeper to nd out who has already attempted
your idea and investigate why they failed. The site autopsy.io chroni-
cles failed startup stories. Timing is likely the most determining factor
for your success; something that failed before might work this time
around as conditions evolve and our expectations shift.
118
The time is right for platform co-ops. East Coast and West-
Coast VCs have predicted 2016 as a year of price and value correction in
the tech startup world. Ultimately, extreme decentralization by block-
chain may prove ungovernable, at least initially. Governance and shared
ownership form the basis of platform co-ops, which are distinct from the
C-Corp, LLC, or even B-Corp (Public Benet Corporation). As tech
startup workers begin contending with severe tax penalties now that
their stock is underwater, re-priced by institutional investors in down-
rounds, the lure of laboring for VC-backed tech startups could begin to
wane. As Silicon Valley’s supremacy falters, platform co-ops purveying
new tech are well poised to oer a better kind of web, one that works
more equitably for the people that create and use it because it promotes
social justice rather than heralds dystopia as prophesied in science ction
co-ownership models.
119
19. DESIGNING POSITIVE
PLATFORMS
MARINA GORBIS
In the early days of digital technologies, we did not have user-interaction
designers. Alan Cooper, one of the pioneers in the eld, wrote an aptly
named book lamenting this state of aairs: The Inmates Are Running the
Asylum. In those days, most of the software interface decisions were made
by engineers, and much too often one needed to be an engineer to use
their creations. Over time, interaction design emerged as a discipline with
a set of rules and conventions, so ordinary people could use many of the
previously forbidding tools. We now know where to put the buttons on
the screen and how many links to embed so that people can get to the
information they need.
Many of today’s on-demand work platforms are the beneciaries
of this body of knowledge. They have mastered the discipline of inter-
action design and brought it to new heights—when it comes to con-
sumer experience. Uber, Munchery, Postmates, and many similar apps
are exquisitely designed, sometimes even addictive for users. They
make previously laborious processes eortless and seamless. Swipe your
phone with a nger and voi—your ride, your meal, your handy-man
magically appear.
But the apps are not only platforms for consumption. They are
quickly becoming entry points for work, gateways to people’s liveli-
hoods. In this sense, whether or not platform creators like it or realize
it, they are engaging in another kind of design—socioeconomic
design. This involves the design of how people structure their work,
earnings, and daily schedules. And here we nd ourselves in the same
120
phase as interaction design was decades ago—the inmates are running
the asylum. The stakes, however, are much higher; instead of just con-
venience, we are talking about livelihoods. Herein lies the urgent need
to develop on-demand platform design as a discipline, and a discipline
that includes not only technological expertise but also the best thinking
from disciplines such as economics, political science, governance, and
others. Otherwise we risk ceding many key social choices about how
we work—what is fair compensation, who owns our work products,
data, and reputations—to platform creators. We embed values into our
technologies, and today such values are reections of Silicon Valley’s
ethos and funding models.
The design of “Positive Platforms”online platforms that not
only maximize prots for their owners but also provide dignied and
sustainable livelihoods for those who work on them—is one of the
most urgent tasks we are facing today. Cooperative ownership struc-
tures give us an opportunity to shape on-demand platforms in a pos-
itive direction. After all, the polarization of economic gains between
platform owners and those who use their apps to earn livelihoods is
one of the biggest dangers in an economy dominated by platforms;
distributed ownership can go a long way in remedying this. Platform
cooperativism also contains promise of a more democratic governance,
with those working on platforms having voice and power to make
good economic decisions from the point of view of owners and plat-
form workers. By themselves, however, these levers may not produce
the desired outcomes. They need to be combined with careful atten-
tion to design elements embedded in platforms themselves.
Platform design choices should arise from the experiences of
people interacting with them, including consumers and platform
workers. To help think about the latter, the Institute for the Future
last year engaged in ethnographic research involving people who are
working on platforms in dierent locations across the United States
San Francisco, New York, Miami, Chicago, and elsewhere. We wanted
to understand the variety of their perspectives and immerse ourselves
in their vocabulary. We recruited study participants with two criteria
121
in mind: the degree of engagement or time spent on platforms (from
passively renting to working full-time) and degree of skill required
(from Uber drivers to those working on HourlyNerd).
Based on this research, we’ve begun to identify some principles
or rules that should guide designers in order to achieve more positive
outcomes for workers:
1. Earnings maximization. It goes without saying that any
platform, cooperative or not, should have a viable economic rationale
for its existence. In addition, however, platforms should and can be
designed to optimize opportunities for those working on them to earn
a good living. Connections between design choices and earnings are
not yet fully understood. Research has suggested, for instance, that
for some types of work people do not do as well nancially when
the platforms set minimum wages as compared to when workers can
set their own wages. Arun Sundararajan and others, as well as our
own observations, have found that platforms on which workers can
organize their own small enterprises, like Airbnb, rather than those in
which workers merely serve the needs of the platform, tend to generate
higher levels of incomes for platform workers. Many platforms can
go a long way in providing services and feedback loops to help those
working on them create more lucrative small businesses.
2. Stability and predictability. We are in a phase of proto-
typing and experimentation in platform design, a practice that is key
to Silicon Valleys style of innovation. But in the case of platforms
this innovation has a direct impact on people’s livelihoods. Imagine if
every month you came to work and your salary were dierent; this is
exactly what many on-demand workers experience today. Participants
in our study, for instance, described shifting pay structures with only
a few days’ notice. Platforms should be structured in ways to mini-
mize such volatility or give workers sucient time or compensation to
adjust to forthcoming changes.
3. Transparency. We need transparency at two levels: at the
level of the platform algorithm itself (so that workers understand
how to increase their earnings) and at the level of archived data (so
122
that those working on platforms understand how their personal data
is being used). Many people we interviewed reported how dicult
it was to gure out how to maximize their earnings on platforms
due to the general opaqueness of the algorithms powering them.
Workers may consequently have trouble calculating their actual
hourly wages or whether it is worthwhile for them to take on cer-
tain tasks.
4. Portability of products and reputations. Reputation is
what powers access to work and ability to earn incomes for those on
platforms. People working on platforms should be able to own the
products of their work and their reputation histories, and carry them
from platform to platform. Platform reputations are often directly tied
to earnings as well as opportunities for various types of work. This
is how one research participant describes the experience of “losing
a reputationas well as the accompanying confusion when a plat-
form was acquired by another company: “All of my portfolio links are
broken now, and I don’t think people can nd me anymore.
5. Upskilling. While traditional career ladders may not be rel-
evant in the world of on-demand work, people still look for oppor-
tunities to increase their levels of skill and expertise. The best plat-
forms already show those who work on them pathways for learning
a particular skill and connect people to resources for advancement.
Upwork, for example, not only provides forums for people to mentor
and provide support for each other but also links them to free and paid
courses where they can acquire desired skills.
6. Social connectedness. Many of today’s workers are creating
communities outside of the platforms where they work to exchange
tips and connect with each other. Reddit, Facebook, Google Groups,
and other social media sites are becoming de facto places for this. As
one person we interviewed said, “I think it’s important for me to build
a relationship with the people that I work with.” Mechanical Turk
workers have come together on a series of forums not only to create a
sense of cohesion but also to advocate for their rights. Platform designers
can make this easier by enabling and fostering such communities.
123
7. Bias elimination. Networks are at the core of what makes
platforms work. Unfortunately, networks can be exclusionary (due to
clustering of people with like minds and backgrounds) and polarizing
(because more connected nodes tend to draw even more connections).
In formal organizations, decades of labor struggles and court rulings
have established some basic rules and principles for non-discriminatory
hiring and promotion. We need to evolve such rules and principles in
platform environments. Platforms could integrate mechanisms for sur-
facing bias as well as eliminating it. Models for this come from some
recent startups such as Knack, which matches people to job opportu-
nities independent of their degrees or demographic characteristics, or
Unitive, which develops software that helps spot unconscious bias in
job descriptions.
8. Feedback mechanisms. It is hard to negotiate with algo-
rithms, and most platforms do not have HR departments for handling
the issues that those working on them encounter daily, from late pay-
ment to unfair reviews. Platforms need to establish feedback mecha-
nisms and equivalents of customer support services for those working
on them. “If I were starting an Internet company or designing an app
for something,” one of our respondents said, “I would say that we
must have phone customer service 24/7, and we must be able to guar-
antee payment.” As platforms come to dominate more sectors of the
economy, customers and workers alike will come to expect eective
means for providing feedback.
These are just some of the early principles we’ve been able to
distill for Positive Platforms. We shouldnt lose sight of the fact that
platform design by itself will not ensure sustainable livelihoods. It is
just one of the levers, along with governance, ownership, and funding
mechanisms. Ownership by itself, for instance, may not guard against
natural network biases or unfair reputation systems. This is why, when
designing cooperative platforms, we need to think about technology
or interaction design along with governance and ownership design.
And let’s not forget that the platform infrastructure also sits within a
larger ecosystem of economic, social, and regulatory frameworks. We
124
need to be thinking about platform design as a part of rethinking this
much larger ecosystem as well.
While in the past most value was created and owed through
formal organizations, networked platforms and protocols are becoming
the new operating systems for value creation. If before we needed layers
of management to coordinate activities—to nd the right people, allo-
cate tasks, and share information—increasingly these are being done
by algorithms. At least for now, these algorithms are created by human
beings, and the stakes for how we design them are high.
125
20. CONVENIENT
SOLIDARITY: DESIGNING FOR
PLATFORM COOPERATIVISM
CAMERON TONKINWISE
Designers aim to make things easier, more productive, or more enjoy-
able. They do this by creating careful interfaces for products, commu-
nications, or physical and digital environments. When well designed,
in ways appropriate to the contexts in which they will be used, things
can:
1. Attract people to undertake certain activities, or to do those activ-
ities more frequently,
2. Bring focus to these activities, and
3. Make those activities more habitual.
It is important to see how these three things are related but also
how they oppose each other. To attract people to do an activity, the
design must t the activity with people’s current habits and expecta-
tions. If someone has to gure out new ways of doing something, it
might obstruct their willingness to follow through on that activity.
This is important when starting to think about the design of platform
co-ops. Sharing has always been an important aspect of being human. But
it has been marginalized by transactional, ownership-oriented systems.
Today, systems that are nonprot or cooperative feel less convenient
than commercial market oerings. That’s why design for platform co-ops
needs to be focused on attracting people.
126
Until now, the design of such systems has leaned toward auto-
mating interactions, mostly as a result of the business-as-usual invest-
ment structures underlying them. Platform cooperatives resist the
extraction of prot that only benets the few by promoting systems
that focus participants on forms of sharing that can enhance the sus-
tainability of everybody in that ecosystem.
How can you design with the aforementioned tensions in mind?
TRADE-OFFS AND OBSTACLES
Some people do things, no matter how eortful, because they believe
in them. But many will engage in a new system only if it aords them
a chance to get something for little or no money or eort. Currently,
successful systems of sharing have taken advantage of smart mobile
devices to lower the eort involved: memberships, proles, and ratings
provide levels of assurance about the transaction; payment systems and
default communications are semi-automated.
I suspect that sharing interactions should always have at least some
of the awkwardness of encounters between peers who do not know
each other so well. An added advantage of designing to retain some
social eort in the interaction is that it disincentivizes those seeking to
scam the system.
In practice, this might mean interfaces that allow a range of
payment types. If the on-demand economy already involves paying
with contributed labor, social friction, and other costs, then inter-
faces designed for platform cooperatives should enable even greater
variability.
Ride-sharing applications already display dierent wait times and
costs for dierent qualities of rides. If extended to display other quali-
ties of those oering the rides—unionized drivers, drivers with health
care coverage included, drivers otherwise currently unemployed
interfaces could aord convenient forms of solidarity; I choose to wait
longer or pay more to benet a certain kind of driver. Despite obvious
127
privacy concerns, such systems could also be used to discourage other
kinds of drivers. But such design systems allow customers to pay more
to subsidize particular in-need workers.
MEMBER PROFILES AND PRONOUNS
Sharing platforms promise, on the one hand, ways of exchanging with
strangers that are not solely money-based and, on the other hand, they
encourage re-establishing exchanges of goods and labor around new
forms of sociality, ones that are less conned and more cosmopolitan.
In many ways, the core of the political potential of sharing economies
lies in the new kinds of social groups that they can sustain. Prior to the
rise of digital platform-based labor economies, these groups tended to
be formal organizations, like community organizations, cooperatives,
or unions. Platform cooperativism presents the possibility that much
of the current sharing economy should be restructured around and
beyond these existing organizations. But the work required to sustain
such structures can limit involvement to those with the time and skills
to do so.
The interaction designer for platform co-ops should therefore
work to enable participants to create and maintain “lighter,” but no
less sustainable, communities. At the outset of what is now called the
sharing economy, many systems were membership-based: for instance,
Zipcar. Current mainstream sharing economy systems require partic-
ipants to have an online account, but most have dropped the rhetoric
of “member.” The dominant players continue to brand themselves as a
community, while users experience the systems more like customers.
There is an opportunity for platform co-op designers to revive the
project of establishing genuine community.
A pivotal touchpoint is the ubiquitous prole page. In the socially
embedded economies of platform co-ops, these play a crucial role
in presenting participants to each other. What information a form
gathers about someone, and then how that information is curated by
128
an interaction designer into a prole that others can see, is axial to the
nature of interactions people in that platform have, including issues of
trust.
In the interaction design of an app, there is often uncertainty
about which pronoun to use to describe a user’s assets: “my photos,
“your music,” “Cameron’s account.” The issue here is not just one of
usability, but of how to describe what it means to cooperate through
this platform. Platform co-op designers should make more strategic
use of “we” and “our,” thereby building a sense of collective own-
ership and mutualism rather than individualism into all aspects of
platforms, including the pronouns used to guide participants.
PROTECTING THE COMMONS
Commons are sometimes considered tragic because of the asymmetry
between individual and collective cost and benet. An individual
might take the risk of exploiting a common resource because the indi-
vidual benet is great, whereas the cost—distributed across many other
people—may not be noticed—unless everyone else similarly exploits
the resource. Because of this asymmetry, commons need to be negoti-
ated through conventions that are actively maintained.
Cooperatives formalize this need to protect the commons. The
interaction designer of more cosmopolitan labor platforms must nd
ways of encouraging these protective actions without overburdening
more distributed participants. The Internet plays an ambiguous role in
this respect. On the one hand, the “true identity” and traceability that
have resulted from monopolies like Google might ensure that indi-
viduals whose actions might be threatening a common resource are
identiable. On the other hand, the anonymity that characterized the
rst decade of the Internet lowered the costs of criticizing the actions
of an exploiter. Today’s interaction designers might therefore allow
participants in a cooperative platform to be at times identiable and at
other times anonymous or collective.
129
The on-demand economy relies heavily on peer-rating systems.
At the moment these tend to take the form of crude numerical schemes
that are known to be ineective, biased, or simply poorly designed. It
is possible for platform co-op interaction designers to make the process
of peer-rating a more nuanced interchange. Opportunities exist for the
“service design” of interchanges among participants that can protect a
commons from degradation.
Designing platform co-ops is an exercise in achieving a new kind
of balance—between ease and eort, between individuality and col-
lectivity, and between privacy and transparency. Designers need to get
this balance right to ensure a platform that encourages constructive
negotiation among members for collective benet.
130
21. DESIGNING FOR PRIVACY
SEDA GÜRSES
Taking privacy seriously is part of what it means to create a democratic,
accountable, and fair platform cooperative. This chapter explores some
of the questions that you, as a platform co-op developer, should be
asking as you design your organization and your platform for privacy.
Privacy is not just a technical matter; it is also a social and political
one. The tools and architectures you may deploy are not neutral and
may pressure the production of the platform in certain ways. These
complexities make governance structures that accompany the tech-
nical evolution of the platform key to developing a healthy and coop-
erative privacy design process.
I propose practical ways to organize just such a process. I draw on
what I’ve learned from seasoned platform cooperativists Felix Weth
(Fairmondo), Emily Lippold Cheney and Noemi Giszpenc (Data
Commons Cooperative), and Alex Rosenblat (Data and Society), who
studies how Uber drivers experience their work.
WHO DOES WHAT
In “sharing” economies, the organization of platforms tends to rely
on a dichotomy between developers and users—and a presumption
that the expertise and decision-making power lie with the developer.
For example, TaskRabbit connects “taskers” and “clients,” which they
refer to collectively as “users”; Uber says they “create opportunities …
and improve the way everyone gets from A to B” inspired by the
131
journeys of their “users and drivers.” Consistently, developers are
depicted as the makers, and users as passive consumers that have to
make do with the developers’ choices.
Through the developer-user dichotomy, sharing-economy plat-
forms erase the material conditions, the experiences, and the needs of
all other parties that contribute to or are aected by the functioning
of the platform. They often externalize a number of social, economic,
and legal risks to the user, leading to a social sorting of those who
cannot bear these risks. For example, these platforms typically estab-
lish trust in their workers-disguised-as-users by exposing personal and
performance information. This means risks from these information
exposures, such as discrimination, are also borne by the users.
You can break out of the user-developer dichotomy by reecting
on your tools, introducing democratic processes, and addressing pri-
vacy issues that most platforms refuse to account for.
CO-OP INFRASTRUCTURES AND THE DIVISION OF
DESIGN LABOR
The platform, conceived predominantly on Silicon Valleys terms, is
not neutral. How, then, do you design a platform for privacy with tools
and processes designed for the extractive data economy?
Felix Weth explained to me, for example, “We decided against
monetizing user data. That takes away the antagonism and allows us
to enter a conversation about how to treat user data.” This is com-
mendable but can also be challenging. Is your platform co-op tech-
nically equipped to operate analytics and authentication on its own
rather than through data-hungry third-parties? Development methods
matter, too: will you use agile development practices to create an envi-
ronment of incessant feature changes? What are some co-opcentric
development practices that can enrich the user-centric models?
Rather than reducing these questions to developer dilemmas
alone, ask the development team to work closely with the co-op’s
132
constituents in rethinking how the platform will be aligned with the
values of the cooperative. A co-op may go a step further by explicitly
recognizing the ways that dierent kinds of participants contribute to
the advancement of the enterprise. This way your constituents’ col-
laborations and contributions can become integral to establishing the
trustworthiness and fairness of the platform, reducing the centrality of
individual worker performance and personal attributes as signiers of
trust. These contributions can be formalized in a governance model
that includes a privacy supervisory board to promote and assure the
accountability of privacy design decisions.
COLLECTIVE INFORMATION PRACTICES AS A
PATHWAY TO PRIVACY DESIGN
Once your governance structure is settled, you can iteratively ask these
three questions to guide your privacy design throughout the evolution
of your platform.
1. What are the practices and activities that will be mediated
through the platform?
Identifying the desired collective information practices is central
to determining the relevant privacy issues for a platform. For example,
should co-op members, clients, and other parties be able to send mes-
sages to each other using the platform? If yes, should they be able to
broadcast messages to all members? Should these messages be visible
to the public, to other co-op members, to clients, or to the platform
administrators? Why or why not? Do all parties understand what is
visible to whom? The answers to these questions determines which
privacy approaches may be appropriate.
2. What are the potential information ows associated with
your collective practices?
133
In a naïve design, in order to enable those practices and activities,
your platform will collect information about all those who engage
with the platform and the surrounding environment. Environmental
indicators may include data to evaluate the performance of the tech-
nical platform, or metrics that capture the activities of co-op members
or clients. Map out and discuss how this information may be collected,
used, or shared with third parties. You will rene this mapping based
on your privacy design.
3. Which approaches to privacy design are appropriate for
the dierent practices?
This is the big one. Within it, consider the three approaches that
follow.
The privacy-as-condentiality approach oers publicly vetted tech-
niques that will allow platforms to minimize data collection and avoid
single points of failure. Oering members end-to-end encrypted pri-
vate messaging, for example, provides the co-op a protection against
coercion or unreasonable search-and-seizure requests from law
enforcement. Techniques based on encryption and secure protocols
may be indispensable for guaranteeing that platform administrators
cannot single-handedly compromise sensitive information related to
practices such as voting, anonymous participation, and reputation sys-
tems. One approach is to use trustworthy third-parties to run polls or
elections, in which case you should take measures to protect the data
collected by the third party and ensure the reliability of the results.
Privacy-as-control approaches focus on access control and trans-
parency. These include measures that the platform can implement to
assure accountability and compliance with data-protection require-
ments. Such mechanisms can also be used to provide platform users
with choices about data collection and processing.
Co-ops may face tensions due to conicts among legal require-
ments. Data protection laws require that platforms make transparent
what data they collect, process, and share, and provide controls over
134
those ows. In contrast, co-op laws may require that members have
access to a detailed member roster. If you publish the roster, you
may inadvertently subject members to spamming, harassment, and
doxing, and risk the abuse of your co-op by commercial competitors.
These risks will most forcefully impact those who do not possess the
social, technical, and legal capital to bear the costs of those risks.
Further concerns may be raised when a third-party service is used,
like Google Analytics or Facebook Groups. Discuss with your co-op
dierent design solutions that allow constituents to control which
information is disclosed to whom while remaining compliant with
transparency requirements.
If your platform is also used to facilitate work, then the platform
potentially needs to comply with laws about workplace surveillance.
Privacy settings and the ability to log o without continued tracking,
as well as mechanisms to examine and dispute the data the platform
tracks, may be vital to providing workers a fair workplace.
Privacy-as-practice approaches involve design principles aimed at
respectful and accountable interactions among all co-op constituents.
Subtle decisions regarding whether legal names will be required, or if
anonymous participation is possible, may impact who is able to speak
and how they are held accountable for their actions. Design principles
like “social translucence” can provide creative alternatives for linking
workers and clients without exposing their personal attributes. A code
of conduct is also essential and should accompany technical mech-
anismsdescribing platform norms, promoting a safe environment,
and outlining procedures for due process.
It is crucial to privacy-as-practice approaches to design the plat-
form in such a way that makes information ows, and their potential
consequences, intuitive. If fullling a certain task has an eect on a
worker’s reputation, or if an algorithm lters work bids based on select
criteria, this causality should be obvious to the parties concerned.
135
22. HOW CROWDFUNDING
BECOMES STEWARDSHIP
DANNY SPITZBERG
Crowdfunding can seem ideal for building cooperative platforms on
the Internet.
Intuitively, this makes sense. Desperation and necessity inspire
many of us to form co-ops. And because co-ops can only accept
non-extractive investment, crowdfunding can look like a great way to
start—a digital barn-raiser that builds community without tapping it
out. In practice, however, many co-ops struggle with crowdfunding.
I believe this is because marketing has skewed our view of crowd-
funding by inuencing how we think and feel about community.
What does “community” really mean here? Community is collective
action with a shared story. We join clubs, co-ops, and campaigns that oer
material benets—things that matter to us on a daily basis—and we stay
because of solidarity with our peers and a purpose we can achieve together.
The more we act collectively, the more we strengthen these incentives.
Incorporating as a co-op is a long way from building community.
While there is a grain of truth to the idea that co-ops are the orig-
inal crowdfunding, people experience co-ops through organizing and
campaigns, not bylaws or business plans. More important, we can’t
extract generosity. That is what marketing tries to do in platform cap-
italism. However, we can form relationships rooted in reciprocity and
generosity through cooperative arrangements.
I learned these lessons last year, when I partnered with Loconomics
to crowdfund their platform and grow their membership. On paper,
Loconomics had a beautiful model: a local services co-op owned by
136
the freelancers doing the work. The user-owners get tools for booking
clients, a growing marketplace, and a dividend based on the co-op’s per-
formance. But the appeal of joining a co-op needed as much validation
as the platform itself.
To research needs, I interviewed a representative group of a dozen
freelancerssome with their own client base, and others nding odd
jobs on platforms like TaskRabbit. Nobody felt misinformed, much
less exploited, with what they get through on-demand service plat-
forms. However, they craved the feeling of belonging to something
bigger. A part-time plumber with a philosophy degree described the
ideal as “less a client base, more a partner base”—in other words, a
co-op. But would anyone pay to join one?
People give endless feedback on ideas, but only commit if they see
value. A sure way to make this shift is through opportunities for people
to test a prototype and express their emotions.
EMOTION WITHOUT EXTRACTION
All emotion is involuntary when genuine,” according to Mark
Twain’s casual wisdom. I believe this rings true for anyone building
co-ops, maybe more than the rst cooperative principle of “voluntary
and open membership.” And for anyone who has run a crowdfunding
campaign, mobilizing genuine emotion can sound like dicult,
draining work.
After working in dozens of campaigns, Ive seen a tension play out
between crowdfunding and membership. Crowdfunding is a one-o
moment of collective action, but when the projects that we care for
also take care of us, people come together and stay together.
How might we reinvent crowdfunding so that collective action
continues?
It’s tempting to search for answers on the Internet. But before
going online, consider the case of a real-life forest. Neera M. Singh,
author of a 2014 forest conservation study in Odisha, India, found
137
a region that challenges the logic of paying individuals to manage
resources as market goods. She observed how villagers harvest only
what wood they need from the forest, and sing songs celebrating its
cool breeze, too. Singh concluded that community stewardship sus-
tains thousands of villages because people organize their labor both
eectively—forming accountable relationships around their work—and
aectivelydeveloping shared identity in the process.
The story of stewardship in Odisha shows another side of crowd-
funding. While starting a project might depend on pooling nancial
contributions, sustaining it requires emotional investment.
Query your favorite search engine for images of “women laughing
alone with salad, and you’ll see a cliché used to evoke health and happi-
ness. I suggest taking a look if you haven’t recently—partly because it’s hard
not to laugh at the fake emotions, but mainly because a similar caricature
shows up in how on-demand service platforms market themselves.
TaskRabbit, for example, portrays images of smiling helpers
cleaning kitchens while women hold babies. Unlike stock photos,
however, we meet TaskRabbit in real life. Their marketing may be
full of clichés, but on-demand service platforms are also full of oppor-
tunities for us to become emotionally invested.
Platforms like TaskRabbit leverage our emotional investment to
grow their user base. Their user experience is designed to delight us,
especially at key moments around transactions. When interacting with
a chef, host, or any service provider who loves their job or gig, we
enjoy acts of kindness that have little to do with rating systems. But
platforms do not support self-organizing. Instead, they leverage com-
munity activity to increase user engagement, and resist attempts to
leave. TaskRabbit charges $500 if you move any consumer-provider
relationship o its platform.
This is the norm in platform capitalism: products extract value
from transactions for outside investors. The platforms connect us to
resources more than they operate as a resource themselves or a place
to gather. In this context, our emotions are more like “laughing alone
with salad” and less like singing together in Odisha’s forests.
138
The real issue with emotions lies with the conditions in which
they are extracted. Emotions on the Internet can be better under-
stood with Arlie Hochschilds theory of “emotional labor,” which
describes how we adapt our emotional expressions in deep and
supercial ways to align with workplace rules. While Singh found
villagers laboring happily, defying market logic, Hochschild argued
more than thirty years ago that emotions get commodied in a cap-
italist service economy.
Looking at how emotions change over time, however, shows
how people become invested. Elizabeth Homan’s 2016 study of
worker co-ops found that embracing emotion ultimately benets
democratic participation. As individuals get comfortable expressing
themselves, they develop an identity as co-owners—their workplace and
co-workers feel like “home” and “family.
Such transformative, humanizing experiences contrast with how
we relate to one another through marketing. These are also how
investment grows into stewardship.
BARN-RAISERS FOR STEWARDSHIP
Happily, my partnership with the Loconomics team ended with their
focusing on community before launching a product. To see what
invitation attracted people most, they swapped their full website for
a simple sign-up page. And to learn about user experience, they wel-
comed service providers and clients to events where they could try the
app, volunteer, or become owners. Getting together nally made it
possible to experience what a community might feel like.
At a minimum, community is a shared feeling of belonging. These
feelings well up when people come together, through book clubs and
parties, and they evaporate when the organization shuts down, puts
up a pay-wall, or simply has a change of heart. This precariousness is
easily overlooked, however, when a platform manages to balance user
satisfaction and extraction.
139
Building community through crowdfunding plays out in a sim-
ilar way. It starts with a goal of mobilizing contributions from many
individuals. With enough incentives and excitement, the possibility
of passing a funding threshold triggers collective action. This usually
happens only once. Very few campaigns lead to what Hochschild calls
“deep acting”—our genuine emotions at work. Most campaigns fall
back on “surface acting,” the kind of behavior associated with fake
smiles. These campaigns strain volunteers, scare supporters, and fail at
their goals. And if a project does get funded, any future collective action
depends on whoever owns and controls the value created. Without
emotional investment in a cooperative arrangement, campaigns run
the risk of ruining relationships over unmet expectations.
For crowdfunding to become stewardship, we need rolling barn-
raisers—regular activities in which guests can co-create with the gifts
they bring, celebrate their accomplishments, and build again.
Marketing strategies extract generosity by developing an audi-
ence, message, and call-to-action, leveraging one-way relationships. A
barn-raiser is an organizing strategy for a cooperative alternative that
involves people, invitation, and engagement (think p-i-e):
Connect with people. Audiences are passive, but people put
emotion at the core of cooperation. Learn who might join the
eort, and what they’re trying to get done.
Make an invitation. Messages are static, but invitations culti-
vate voluntary and open membership. Dene what you want
to celebrate, together—in person or online.
Sustain engagement. A call-to-action limits inputs, but
engagement supports democratic ownership and control.
Seek participation more than nancial contributions.
By starting small and learning along the way, barn-raisers can
“grow the pie” for co-ops. This is how crowdfunding becomes stew-
ardship: raising expectations, embracing the challenge, and sharing the
value as community grows.
140
23. ECONOMIC BARRIERS
AND ENABLERS OF
DISTRIBUTED OWNERSHIP
ARUN SUNDARARAJAN
In May 2015, I chatted with OuiShare’s co-founders Antonin Léonard
and Benjamin Tincq during their OuiShare Fest, the annual gathering
of over a thousand sharing-economy enthusiasts in Paris. I sensed a
tension at the Fest between the purpose-driven and prot-driven par-
ticipants: those who saw the sharing economy as a path to a more
equitable and environmentally sensible world, and those who were
excited by the massive infusions of venture capital into hundreds of
burgeoning sharing-economy platforms.
Léonard spoke of the confusion and disappointment he detected
from those who had hoped that the sharing economy would really
change the world. “And because there was so much hope, the ones that
were once so hopeful are now so disappointed, in a way,” he said. “But
maybe the problem is not so much how much money was invested, but
why did we have this hope?
Tincq, while agreeing with the perception of growing disen-
chantment, was focused on a simpler point: that the shift away from
purpose and toward prot was driven primarily not by a change in
philosophy but by a need for growth capital. In his view, at the time,
for a nascent platform to bridge the early-stage gap and get to critical
mass, there was no practical alternative to venture capital.
Tincq’s point echoed a theme from a panel discussion I had organ-
ized about new ownership models at the 2014 Social Capital Markets
141
conference with Janelle Orsi, Lisa Gansky, and Adam Werbach. A
frequently raised theme was how the model of corporate ownership
lends itself naturally to the acquisition of large amounts of capital in
exchange for outside ownership. In particular, Werbach, a long-time
social entrepreneur and co-founder of Yerdle (a shareholder-owned
platform that facilitates the ecologically responsible exchange of house-
hold assets using a virtual currency), reected on the challenges he
faced looking for ways in which he could structure Yerdle as a coop-
erative while still preserving the ability to raise the external nancing
he knew would be necessary to realize his vision.
In light of these and other conversations, I nd the excitement about
platform cooperatives—especially in the form of sharing-economy
platforms owned by their providers and funded through mechanisms
other than institutional venture capital—both inspiring and conta-
gious. Presented with these new possibilities, it seems instructive to
examine why worker cooperatives mediate a relatively tiny fraction of
economic activity in the United States today. There were over 30,000
cooperatives operating in 73,000 U.S. locations in 2009, holding assets
over $2 trillion, and generating revenues of over $650 billion. While
this scale is not trivial, it is dwarfed by the corresponding success of
shareholder corporations. The Fortune 500—the ve hundred largest
corporations in the United States—collectively generated over $12.5
trillion in revenue in 2015, and the total 2009 cooperative take of $650
billion is less than the corresponding sum of the revenues of just the
two largest corporations, Walmart and ExxonMobil.
Economic theory suggests that worker cooperatives are more e-
cient than shareholder corporations when (1) there isn’t a great deal of
diversity in the levels of contribution across workers; (2) when the level
of external competition is low; and (3) when there isnt the need for
frequent investments in response to technological change. This is one
reason why a U.S.–based worker cooperative like Sunkist (formerly the
California Fruit Exchange, an entity that has, since 1893, been entirely
owned by citrus fruit growers), has thrived, where other types of coop-
eratives have failed to emerge at scale. Perhaps the businesses that have
142
fueled much of the worlds economic growth in recent decades have
instead been in highly competitive industries, leveraging specialized
high-variance talent and requiring large technological investments.
But if one thinks about it, today’s sharing-economy platforms
do exhibit some characteristics in common with Sunkist, and a
worker-owned equivalent to Lyft and Uber seems quite feasible.
Point-to-point urban transportation is a fairly uniform service in an
industry with a limited amount of competition. Once the technology
associated with “e-hail” and logistics is commoditized, which it will
be, the economic fundamentals for the emergence of a platform coop-
erative would appear to be in place.
More important, the network eects associated with ridesharing
are geographically concentrated. Thus, unlike platforms such as eBay
and Facebook, the barriers to entry posed by an incumbent platform
may not be onerous. True, passengers gravitate toward the platforms
with more drivers, and vice versa. However, these eects are localized.
Most potential passengers in New York care little about the scale of a
platform in Los Angeles or Minneapolis. They want the service that
has the densest supply in their own city. Furthermore, it is relatively
simple for a driver to “multihome,” or be a provider on multiple plat-
forms. In other words, each local market is contestable. The same is
true for many labor platforms, including those that provide domestic
work and home services.
As a consequence, instigating the emergence of a platform coop-
erative doesn’t involve getting millions or billions of users to switch
simultaneously. Rather, it might be seeded simply by signing up a few
thousand providers. One such eort under way as of the writing of this
essay is Swift in New York, a nascent ridesharing eort that hopes to
organize as a driver cooperative.
Despite these relatively low barriers to entry, a collective that
hopes to build a scalable platform business with a cooperative own-
ership model faces other challenges. During a panel that Juliet Schor
and I participated in at the Platform Cooperativism conference,
Schor highlighted an issue her research had uncovered about sharing
143
economy cooperatives: that their value system was often better articu-
lated than their value proposition. Put dierently, cooperatives tended
to focus too much on how the value would be shared rather than on a
compelling oer to create the value in the rst place.
Perhaps part of the solution will come from the possibility, cre-
ated by blockchain technologies, of “distributed collaborative organ-
izations,” or DCOs—new decentralized collectives that, in the eyes
of pioneers like Matan Field of Backfeed and Vitalik Buterin of
Ethereum, can use rules embedded in computer code to align the
incentives of dierent contributors, of nancial capital, of expertise, of
labor, and of participation. These DCOs are connected intellectually
to a variety of related decentralized ownership models. They range
from the FairShare Model of Karl Sjogren, which proposes a structure
of dierent classes of ownership shares for dierent contributors—for
founders, people with a continuous working role, for users, and for
investorsto the Swarm approach to “crypto-equity” crowdfunding
developed by Joel Dietz. If the rules for equitable value distribution are
well dened, generally accepted, and become “normal” in the same
way that employment for salary at a shareholder corporation was in the
twentieth century, perhaps the providers can then focus more of their
eorts on creating value.
However, as groups of motivated providers address the challenge
raised by Schor, and as experimentation and the quest for normalcy
across dierent platform cooperative and DCO models continues,
redistributing platform value using a more familiar routestock
ownershipseem like a promising near-term prospect. In the United
States, employee stock ownership programs, or ESOPs, that share own-
ership with employees by allocating stock to them are quite common.
ESOPs create joint ownership as well as a form of prot sharing. And
the scale of an ESOP can be quite signicant. For example, in 1995,
the United Airlines ESOP owned 55 percent of the company.
Creating similar “provider” stock ownership programs—under
which providers are allocated shares in a platformseems quite nat-
ural. An early example of a platform that aims to do this is Juno, a
144
ridesharing service started by Talmon Marco, the independently
wealthy founder of the messaging company Viber. Juno has committed
to ensuring that its drivers own 50 percent of the company’s founding
stock by 2026. And the scale of such wealth division need not be as
absolute. In early 2016, Managed by Q, a labor platform for oce ser-
vices, allocated 5 percent of its equity for its providers.
The parallel with United Airlines seems especially relevant
because its ESOP emerged as part of a negotiation between organized
labor and management, at a time when the company’s survival was
threatened by pilot unions. Sharing-economy platforms rely heavily
on motivated providers to maintain their brand by delivering a con-
sistent high-quality service experience. Granted, the prospect of auto-
mation will weaken the clout of labor in the long run. But in the near
term, dierent digitally enabled provider collectives, manifestations
of the idea of “new power” from Jeremy Heimans and Henry Timms,
will likely increase providers’ bargaining power. As this happens, more
widespread provider stock ownership programs may well be a nat-
ural response, and perhaps the most pragmatic prospect for sharing the
wealth of the sharing economy.
145
24. THERE IS PLATFORM-
POWER IN A UNION
RA CRISCITIELLO
Venturing into the new world of platform cooperativism, to those of
us in organized labor, has felt a lot like making a deal with the devil.
Our new partners in the tech industry undoubtedly feel similarly
about us.
It is no secret that unions are dying. Private sector unions have
dismal density, and public sector unions are not faring much better.
Attacks in many forms—including what we’ve seen with court cases
like Harris v. Quinn, and now in Friedrichsare legal blows that high-
light the forces assembled against workers. Organized labor has largely
retained its familiar tactics and worldview despite the reality that the
economic structures of employment have been turned on their heads.
If unions cannot solve labors woes, it may not be simply because
organized labor is dying, but rather because organized labor needs to
change.
That is why members of SEIU-United Healthcare Workers West,
in partnership with a tech startup, are collaborating to create a work-
er-owned cooperative of licensed vocational nurses, or LVNs, who
can be dispatched on demand to patients’ homes through a mobile or
online device. Despite being skilled workers, LVNs in Californiaa
workforce largely of women and immigrants—have seen their work
prospects diminish, partly as a result of registered nurses expanding
their own scope of practice. LVNs can give vaccinations, treat wounds,
and deal with most low-acuity issues. But they need new tools to nd
clients and secure livelihoods. The tech company they’re working with
146
is a separate team of entrepreneurs who see the need, as the work-
er-owners do, to create an on-demand technology that values workers
as much as it values investors or the technology itself.
There are two paths emerging at the intersection of organized
labor and cooperative employment models. Both address the realities
of an increasingly casual and insecure economy that oers workers
scarce or nonexistent benets.
One is an industrial model of cooperative organizing. It looks at
how workers’ rights and protections are diminishing—benets like
workers’ compensation, health insurance, training and development,
retirement savings, and sick leaveand tries to ght that tide on scale.
This means creating a structure where those benets are not, as they his-
torically have been, contingent on a worker’s employment relationship
with a particular employer. The Freelancers Union, for instance, aggre-
gates the self-employed worker community into a visible industry. Aside
from the sheer naming and negotiating power that comes with uniting
formerly disaggregated workers, aliating with an organization enables
a self-employed worker to gain access to things like group-rate benets.
The second path is smaller-scalefashioned after pre-industrial
guilds. Nursing within the LVNs’ scope of practice lends itself to the
guild model, where formal licensure and training is needed, and years of
apprenticeship and job placement can help advance the profession. The
worker cooperative is building the type of labor market that its members
want to see. As the members say in their founding mission statement, their
goals are “high-quality, convenient health care on-demand, to grow the
LVN profession as well as employment opportunities for highly-trained
LVNs, and to increase access to care.
By monopolizing the labor supply in a particular narrow market,
organized labor can use the union worker cooperative model to enable
workers to own their own labor and enjoy portable benets, thanks
to a collective bargaining agreement between the cooperative and
the union. The cooperative guild can start on a manageable level by
restricting the co-op work to one classication (like the LVN), but it
can later scale to include multiple job classications.
147
What both of these paths signify is the potential for value when
organized labor and worker cooperatives team up in the “gig economy.
Together, they can protect workers’ rights while also embracing the
exibility both in workers’ lives and in consumer demand that increas-
ingly seems to be the way of the future. On the ground, this has meant
listening deeply to workers and being honest about how employment
will continue to change.
During an early board meeting, one LVN described feeling
scared that her phlebotomist coworkers would soon be out of a job
if health care careers that require only a few months of training
become “on-demand-ed.” The truth is that she may be right.
Healthcare workers who do skilled work but whose positions
require less than a year or two of training will likely see their work
leave the connes of hospital walls. The LVNs are developing a
platform worker cooperative to get ahead of precisely that trend.
They see change coming, and they want to be in the driver’s seat so
they can make sure that workers’ rights are protected.
The LVN worker cooperative is not just about sharing ownership,
governance, and prot. It’s about worker-owners controlling their
own labor.
The need for startup capital has become complicated, however,
given the rightfully uncompromising standards of platform coopera-
tivism. In order that early investors and others oriented toward prot
maximization don’t gain undue control over the LVN co-op, the
members and their startup partner may need to negotiate an agree-
ment; they need to set up guidelines for the relationship between
them, for instance, and for how they contract with outside entities. In
the process, the co-op needs to reconcile its own democratic structure
with the venture capital model that is nancing the startup. Neither
the co-op nor the startup can succeed without the other, so any success
or prot should be shared by both.
When members of the co-op and startup met with a venture
capital rm early on, the LVNs described feeling how the investor’s
drive to extract capital could easily become antithetical to the co-op
148
model, which should allow members to decide how best to reinvest
their earnings. Several potential venture capital partners explained
that they would require a signicant role in the co-op’s governance
as an assurance for their investment. The co-op board has struggled
with what amount of outside control it should be unwilling to give
up. Democratic, one-worker-one-vote principles feel, at a gut level,
at odds with the capital that the platform needs to grow. Through its
bylaws, for now, the co-op has carefully drawn lines around demo-
cratic decision-making and reinvestment. It may go without saying
that union members are used to threats from those who want to eradi-
cate or exploit them, so they know how to guard the castle.
What unions oer platform cooperatives is possibly the greatest
remaining power of any union: the ability to leverage collective
power. This may mean the collective buying power to purchase port-
able employee health care insurance on scale, or the capacity to grow
a skilled workforce by providing training and apprenticeship opportu-
nities, or the possibility of creating a worker-centered marketplace like
the LVNs’ platform. If worker cooperatives and platform cooperatives
are the employers of the future, also, union revenues will come from a
dierent source: the cooperative worker herself. The new model moves
unionized labor away from entrenched us-versus-them labor relations
and lets workers take power directly instead of negotiating for it.
One thing is very clear: all the stakeholders in this new model are
taking a leap of faith, trusting that our shared vision of a new employ-
ment model will come close enough to satisfying the ethical impera-
tives of each group. So here we go. There’s a little bit of devil in all of
us, but maybe we can still cooperate.
149
25. MAKING APPS FOR
LOW-WAGE WORKERS AND
THEIR NEIGHBORHOODS
SASKIA SASSEN
How can digital cooperative platforms contribute to better work
lives of low-income workers by addressing the specic needs of these
workers, at their workspace and in their neighborhoods? What I
describe here is inspired by the concept of platform cooperativism: an
ecosystem of apps that could address common needs of low-income
workers and their neighborhoods.
Such an ecosystem of apps would be one more step toward mobi-
lizing localities around initiatives concerning both workplace and
neighborhood issues. This matters, given settings where hardships
and losses do not always facilitate trust among neighbors. One way
of thinking about my argument is that it is a search for material con-
ditions (e.g., access to cooperative platforms within and across neigh-
borhoods) upon which more complex non-material relationships can
be built (e.g., backup support at the workplace, and more aspirational
aspects such as trust and solidarity).
The high-end worker is already a full and eective user of
these technologies; in the United States, most digital applications
have been geared toward high-end workers and households, and
to scientic collaboration. Very little has been developed to meet
the needs of low-income workers, their families, and their neigh-
borhoods. This is a bad and sad state of aairs given the needs of
these workers and families, especially since the data indicate that
150
they have digital access and are willing to spend on apps; but they
are mostly conned to mass-market goods, notably music. We also
know that digital access is overwhelmingly through their phones.
We need more innovations that meet the needs and constraints of
low-wage workers. Platform co-ops like Coopify are stellar exam-
ples of that.
TRANSFORMING THE NEIGHBORHOOD
INTO A SOCIAL BACK-UP SYSTEM
My argument and proposal regarding low-wage workers is the exten-
sion of digitization to the larger space within which these workers
operate: not only the workplace narrowly understood, but also, and
very important, their neighborhood. Apps for low-income workers
and their neighborhoods can become part of the larger ecosystem
of platform cooperativism. This is already a fact among high-end
workers: digitization has become a way of restructuring the con-
nection between work and home. It is inconceivable today that the
high-end worker can or does simply leave it all behind when closing
the door of her oce for the day—on those few days every week
when s/he might actually work in the oce. We might say the cor-
relation for the low-wage worker is that it is a ction that s/he can
simply leave it all behind when s/he closes the door of her home and
goes to work.
The home and the neighborhood have long been support spaces
for the working class. Today this is rarer, mostly due to changes in the
condition of low-wage workers. Digitization can help rebuild some
strength in these spaces. For instance, in the case of trouble (a sick child
of a parent who is at work, police violence, etc.) an app on all residents’
phones can enable quick deployment of stationary neighbors— grand-
mothers, hairdressers, and shop-keepers. This is also a rst step toward
greater neighborhood integration and expanded use of diverse digital
capabilities.
151
UNDERUTILIZATION OF DIGITAL TOOLS AND
APPS IN LOW-INCOME NEIGHBORHOODS
This underutilization is a sharp contrast with the case of high-end
workers. It constructs a radical dierentiation between workspace and
neighborhood for low-wage workers. This is disabling and adds to the
diculties in their daily life at and o work.
We must ask what can we do with current technologies but are not
doing because of diverse reasons: lack of resources, lack of motivation,
lack of interest in low-income households, individuals, and localities,
and so on. Important, and too often overlooked, is that the types of
applications that are being developed mostly do not address the needs
and limited resources of low-income workers, their households, and
their neighborhoods. That is why platform co-ops should rethink their
value proposition.
In a recent overview, the Pew Center found that 45 percent of U.S.
households with less than $30K per year and 39 percent of those with
$30K$50K use mobile phones as their primary digital access. Email at
home is rare, and often relies on low-bandwidth dial-up. Researching
the use of digital technologies by women across the world on behalf
of the United Nations Development Program, I found extensive use
of mobile telephones by modest-income and poor women in Africa: it
allowed them to run their businesses, mostly diverse small-scale trading.
USEFUL APPS FOR LOW-INCOME WORKERS AND
NEIGHBORHOODS
Several eorts are beginning to address these needs. Here are a few
examples of mostly recent applications geared to modest-to-low-
income households and neighborhoods. Kinvolved is an app for
teachers and after school program leaders that makes it easy for them
to connect to parents in case of a students lateness or absenteeism.
Many poor neighborhood schools lack easy communication with a
152
student’s home; this has allowed self-destructive conduct to worsen,
damaging a student’s chances for a job or acceptance to college. This
app is simple and straightforward: when a teacher, or a coach, or who-
ever is part of the student’s adult network at school, takes attendance or
sees something of concern, the family is immediately notied via text
messages or email updates—whichever they prefer. The low-income
worker knows that if there is trouble s/he will be alerted.
Another app, developed by Propel, simplifies applying for
government services, a notoriously time-consuming process. Now
there is the option of a simple mobile enrollment application. Yet
another such application is Neat Streak, which lets home cleaners
communicate with clients in a quick non-obtrusive way. There
is also a money-management app for mobiles that combines cash
and loan requests, again simplifying the lives of very low-income
people who need to cash their paychecks before payday, and can
avoid the high interest rates charged by so called “payday sharks.
A very dierent type of app from the aforementioned is Panoply
(presented by Robert Morris): an online intervention that replaces a
health professional with a crowd-sourced response to individuals with
anxiety and depression. What I nd signicant here is that it has the
added eect of mobilizing a network of people, which may be one step
in a larger trajectory of support that can also become a local neighbor-
hood network. Panoply coordinates support from crowd workers and
unpaid volunteers. It incorporates recent advances in crowdsourcing
and human computation, enabling timely feedback and quality vet-
ting. Crowds are recruited to help users think more exibly and objec-
tively about stressful events.
Another useful tool seeks to develop new ways of working
together online. This is something quite common among middle-class
users and in certain professional jobs, but far less likely among low-
income workers. But it could be useful to the latter; it can enable a
sense of the individuals worth to a network (“I matter to my commu-
nity”), and thereby feed solidarity and mobilization around issues of
concern to low-income neighborhoods, families, and workers.
153
NEW CHALLENGES THAT CALL FOR NEIGHBORHOOD
COLLECTIVE ACTION
Neighborhoods are important spaces for low-wage workers. In
the past they often enabled union organizing and the formation of
mutual-assistance organizations. Much of this is lost today. There
is work to be done to strengthen this neighborhood function. But
this can only happen if the neighborhood is a space for connecting,
collaborating, and mutually recognizing each other. Given the devel-
opment of apps geared to low-wage workers, platform cooperativism
could enable signicant scale-ups in the deployment of such apps and
in their spread. One key mode of scale-up would be shared own-
ership and shared governance. This would have the added eect of
enabling collaboration among workers and among residents within
and across neighborhoods, joining hundreds of years of the history
of cooperatives with the digital economy. I see here beginnings of
possibly new social histories.
154
26. THE CROWD:
NATURALLY COOPERATIVE,
UNNATURALLY SILENCED
KRISTY MILLAND
When you think of a crowd, youll likely envision large numbers of
people, many voices, and the wisdom of a variety of viewpoints. In
crowd work, all of these features are what makes the platforms so
useful; work is done quickly by many with a variety of skill sets and
abilities, and their group wisdom leads to a high-quality product.
It only makes sense that the future should bring us self-governing
crowds, those who run their own platforms to ensure that their needs
are respected equally with those of the businesses that leverage their
labor for a prot. To date, however, not only has no such collabo-
rative crowd work platform emerged, but the voice of the workers
themselves has mostly been ignored in the discussions about cre-
ating these platforms. If we are to move forward into a future of
labor where many existing jobs are displaced by robots or algorithms,
relegating us to work on crowd platforms, we must design online
workplaces that are run collaboratively, or we will all be beholden to
exploitative companies who do not have the workers’ best interests
at heart.
As a worker on Amazon Mechanical Turk (mTurk), I know insult
and exploitation rsthand. For example, this week I decided to set
aside an entire day in order to make as much money as possible. Out
of the eight hours I spent on mTurk, I was able to complete 166 tasks,
called “HITs,” and I earned only $19.64.
155
The rst problem is how much eort it takes to nd work; I can’t
just restrict myself to good work, I have to instead do any work that is
available in order to make money at all—but even that is limited as
I’m Canadian and most HITs are qualied only for U.S. workers. This
discrimination makes no sense for most work on the platform, since
Canadians can tag photos, categorize sentiment, or transcribe text just
as well as their American neighbors, but I’m excluded regardless.
Next, accepting just any HIT exposed me to some horric content,
such as a survey with at least eight videos of either really happy or really
sad or violent content, the title of which was something along the lines
of, “Does this make you cry?” It took me at least an hour to recover
emotionally and physically from that HIT alone, which means that I
had an entire hour of wasted time. The pay? $2.75 for 50 minutes. Had I
realized what the content was about and how long it would take, I would
have never accepted the HIT, but the content was not fully described
upfront. In the past, I have been faced with HITs that included ISIS
murder videos or animal abuse, or worse. This is what I have to do to
generate income as an mTurk worker, and it is damaging to my soul. Yet
if I have no other avenue for income, it is my only option.
One of the platform’s most egregious abuses is allowing workers
to go unpaid for work completed to the best of their ability. Amazon
not only condones this wage theft but has made it a feature, since the
employer who posts work gets to see what is submitted in order to
adjudicate it. All employers have to do is reject the worker, denying
them payment, and they get to keep both the work and their cash. It is
scraping the bottom of the barrel when a worker not only has to face
being paid pennies per hour for their hard work, but also the possibility
of not being paid at all.
Many people assume that workers such as myself are all from
developing countries, are unskilled, barely speak English, have no
education, and will cheat to steal money from those who post work on
the platform. It gets worse, with comments about the fact that we are
literally the unwashed masses in our pajamas doing work for pennies
an hour, the lumpenproletariat so clueless that it is a favor to pay us
156
even a pittance in order to give us any job at all. This is utter garbage,
as studies clearly show we are highly skilled and educated workers (see
Amazon Mechanical Turk (mTurk) workers are highly educated” at
TurkerNation.com), the bulk of whom come from the United States.
We are now awakening to a class consciousness. We are beginning to
push back against the drive to put us to work so unethically.
In attempting to speak out about the horrors we face on the job,
we’ve realized that those outside the system have no idea what is going
on inside. Journalists seem oblivious to the fact that while a robot may
not yet be able to perfectly replicate the writing style of a talented
human author, a group of humans can, and cheaply. The job of writing
for the news is likely to be one of the rst to fall to crowd work, but
the eld will quickly eat up other careers as well. Crowd platforms
are being tested to replace doctors (CrowdMed), software developers
(TopCoder, InnoCentive), graphic designers (99designs), interior
designers (CoContest), and more. There are few jobs that require a
degree of skill or education that could not be matched by the crowd.
If we allow the status quo to march ahead, with platforms that are
designed to support abuse and no legislation to stop worker exploitation,
then it wont just be the lumpenproletariat screaming for change. It will
be you, your mother, your sister, your daughter, and everyone you know
and love being paid pennies an hour—if they are lucky enough not to
have their work rejected or stolen. As Torben Schenk, a critical political
economist and an advisor to a member of European Parliament, put it at
a recent workshop, we must view the current eld of crowd work as a
juggernaut plowing downhill, and we can no longer jump out of its way.
I don’t claim to know what the perfect platform design is, but
when designing for a crowd, one must engage the crowd in active
dialogue in order to nd the answer. At the Platform Cooperativism
conference, the intent was for a widely varied group of people to talk,
generate knowledge, and move forward to take action. Many loud
voices were heard, and others lurked in the background taking notes.
But one sad fact I faced rsthand was that the crowd workers were not
there in force. On top of that, at the Worker Voice panel, where Karla
157
Morales and Zenayda Bonilla discussed how their own cooperatives
operated, and I described my experience with mTurk, there were very
few people in the audience. I attended many other panels and talks, and
it seemed like the audience was hungry to hear how they could create
their own cooperatives, but they mostly looked to me like experts in
business or law, or CEOs of cooperatives, although that seems like an
oxymoron to me. This must end here.
While you can copy a blueprint already created, and must consider
legalities as you strive to form, there is no voice more important than
that of the workers. Without workers you cannot have a cooperative.
I would hate to see so much eort and time put into developing a
platform, only to have it fail because it does not t the needs of the
workers it was expected to serve. If you want to know what will work,
ask those who will work on the platform.
It is clear that the labor platforms we have now aren’t working for
those who use them. Features such as easy communication and protec-
tion from exploitation are ignored in favor of isolation and wage theft,
while the companies that run the platforms continue to turn a prot.
Even though it may only be a few million people who are working
full-time on such platforms right now, the speed, low cost, and ease
of getting work done through the crowd means careers will disappear
one by one as the crowd takes over those jobs. No matter who you
are, you will see at least parts of your job taken o your desk, and that
means portions of your income will disappear along with them. We
must stand together and create places of work that allow the crowd to
set its own standards, enact its own protections, and alter the future of
work to be balanced between worker and employer rights.
We cannot do so without listening to the voices of those who are
already using such platforms—both the crowd and those who leverage
them. If you want to protect the future of labor by protecting the lab-
orers, the time to put workers’ expertise at the helm is now. Dystopian
or not, a future in which we are all forced to work on something like
Amazon Mechanical Turk is not out of the picture unless we change
the frameby creating the competition ourselves.
158
27. PLATFORMS AND TRUST:
BEYOND REPUTATION
SYSTEMS
TOM SLEE
Do new technologies embed a set of values?
Some contributors to this book argue that platform cooperatives can
clone and change the ownership structure of existing platforms. This
assumes that the technology stack is essentially neutral; it can be operated
for private prot or it can be operated for cooperative goals, at the behest
of its owners. For others, the technology stack is not neutral. Embedded
within it are the values of the project. Even if technology does not deter-
mine outcomes, technologies have “aordances” that favor some out-
comes over others. According to this view, the networked structure of
the Internet has certain aordances for democratic politics and decentral-
ized organization; the use of free and open source software is a political
commitment to openness as well as a technological one. The enthusiasm
for the blockchain—the distributed, decentralized ledger that provides
the basis for Bitcoin and other digital currencies—is a recent expression
of the same idea, even if the particular values are dierent.
Consider, for instance, rating systems. Many see rating systems as
another technology that embeds a democratic and egalitarian politics.
Rating systems have become an alternative to experts. No longer do
we have to rely on an elite class of old-guard establishment critics to
guide our tastes: we can do it ourselves. We rate books on Amazon,
lms on Netix, restaurants on Yelp; it’s the democratization of
criticism and recommendation.
159
Reputation systems are a special case of rating systems, in which
people rate other people, conferring on them a reputation. Some see
reputation systems as the primary innovation of the sharing economy.
We can get into strangers’ cars, eat at their tables, stay in their homes,
or lend money to people we will never meet—all because rat-
ings-driven reputation systems seem to have solved the problem of
trust between strangers. For their proponents, these systems come with
particular embedded values of democratization and decentralization:
Tim O’Reilly, for instance, believes we may be entering a new era
of “algorithmic regulation,” in which reputation systems replace cre-
dentials and inspections once provided by public agencies. We don’t
need cumbersome regulations to ensure good behavior, we can do it
ourselves.
The promise of reputation systems, and the claim that they
democratize trust, are largely mirages; they do not embed values that
some think they do.
Even though reputation systems look and feel like product-rating
systems, it turns out that we act dierently when we rate people to
when we rate products. The dierence shows up in the rating distribu-
tion: on Netix or on Yelp, reviews on a ve-star scale show a peak at
a value between three and four stars, and tail o to either side, with a
smaller but signicant number of ones and ves. On sharing economy
platforms, most ratings are in the four-star or ve-star range. We can
call these “Lake Wobegon systems,” after the town in the Garrison
Keillor short stories where “all the children are above average.” Such
systems fail to discriminate among good and bad service providers,
and researchers have conrmed that there is often no real relationship
between rating and quality. There is no evidence that an Uber driver
with a rating of 4.9 is better than one with a rating of 4.6, even though
the latter is in danger of being kicked o the Uber platform.
One underlying reason for the Lake Wobegon eect is that when
we are unhappy at an interaction, many people follow the maxim
if you can’t say anything nice, say nothing at all.” Some leave no
rating after a substandard Airbnb visit because they do not want the
160
awkwardness that may go along with putting out a negative evalu-
ation for the world to see. A reputation system acts as a guestbook
at a bed-and-breakfast or a small museum: we leave comments and
it looks nice, but it does not solve the hard problems of establishing
trust. On eBay, a pioneer in online reputation, 99 percent of ratings
are positive, even though one investigation put the number of dissat-
ised participants at about 20 percent. When people rate each other
on reputation systems most are generally being polite, not rendering
judgment. This is perfectly appropriate behavior, but it makes the
reputation systems useless.
The distorted rating distributions serve the interests of the platform
owners, making the platform appear to be a higher-trust environment
than it really is. Because of missing reviews and our tendency to be
polite, reputation systems hide the level of dissatisfaction on a platform.
A second problem with reputation systems is that, even if most rat-
ings are positive, providers live in fear of the occasional bad review that
pushes them down in the search results or gets them removed from the
platform entirely, depriving them of their livelihood. Service providers
on a platform with a reputation system live in a Panopticonalways
being watched, always being assessed. It’s like living in an environ-
ment covered by unreliable CCTV cameras, which record images that
may or may not reect reality. Faced with the threat of a bad review,
some service providers engage in compliant, indulgent, “emotional
labor,” catering to the whims of their most entitled customers. Drivers
may or may not be good drivers, but they probably will not show it
if they are in a bad mood. Bad reviews often have little to do with
an objective evaluation; such systems have been shown to reect and
hence perpetuate patterns of prejudice among those doing the ratings.
Are there ways to tweak rating systems so they work better? It’s
a tempting proposition, but I think it is a dead-end. Most of us avoid
giving bad ratings for good reasons: mutual assessment and reporting is
a snitch system, incompatible with friendly and collaborative peer-to-
peer relationships. It’s a set of behaviors that belongs in a police state,
and which has little place in an open and democratic society.
161
So how else could we deal with trust on platforms? While there
are no simple and reliable answers, there are many sources of inspira-
tion inside and outside the world of technology. Here are a few.
Some platforms avoid the problem completely. Craigslist and
Kijiji make no claim to vouch for the parties in an exchange, and they
expect buyers to beware. Like other listing services, they avoid getting
involved in the actual transaction between buyer and seller, and take
only a small fee from advertisers as their income. Stocksy United is
another site that does not have a big need for a trust system because
there is little room for deception; a photograph is what it is, and can be
displayed and seen on the site before purchase.
Other successful technology-oriented communities have adopted
a mixture of approaches. Internally, personal recommendations or
one-on-one mentoring can play an important role, as in the Debian
community that produces a leading Linux distribution. Personal invi-
tations can also help to lter out unwanted members, as in the arXiv
community that maintains an important pool of scientic papers and
working papers. Wikipedia has its messy hierarchies and occasional
lapses into efdoms, but remains remarkable for all that—or maybe
because of all that—and its graduation of articles where trust is needed
(“controversial places”) helps to limit the need for formality.
Platform cooperatives share a problem with VC-funded platforms:
the platform owner has an incentive to make the platform community
appear to be working well, and to downplay or hide problems that
arise. Any trust system needs to be externally auditable to have any
credibility. We know very little about how (or if ) Airbnb or Uber rep-
utation systems really work, because they are hidden. The incentives
to cover up failures become particularly strong when fortunes depend
on a successful IPO. If there is not a signicant tension between an
independent auditor and system owner, then the system is probably
not doing its job.
Unlike VC-funded platforms, platform cooperatives should accept
independent external audits of what actually happens on the platform.
The experience of fair-trade activists provides a source of inspiration:
162
consumers pay a premium for products that support a fair supply chain,
and economists Kimberly Ann Elliott and Richard Freeman have
looked into the fair trade certication systems that seek to establish
trust (how do we know the producers are following through on their
claims?). They went into their study expecting that the most eective
system would feature one well-recognized certication system, and
were surprised to nd that an ecosystem of competing certicate pro-
grams had many benets.
There is a need for similar independent certication programs
around platform cooperative oerings. The best forms for such pro-
grams will be discovered by experimentation, and here cooperatives
have a real advantage. Venture-funded platforms are impelled to
deliver a successful IPO exit for their investors, and so have too much
to lose from a bad report. Maybe platform cooperatives can avoid the
closed and secretive character of those companies, and experiment in
the open.
163
28. WHY PLATFORM CO-OPS
SHOULD BE OPEN CO-OPS
MICHEL BAUWENS AND VASILIS KOSTAKIS
“What if this was no longer capitalism, but something worse?
McKenzie Warks statement, which opens his chapter in this book,
eloquently summarizes the growing criticism of prot-maximizing
business models within the so-called collaborative sharing economy.
That “something worse” appears to take the form of a new kind of
feudalism. If feudalism was based on the ownership of land by an elite,
the resource now controlled by a small minority is networked data. We
cannot, therefore, be content with cooperative alternatives designed to
counter mere capitalism.
Commons-based peer production, a term coined by Yochai
Benkler, has brought about a new logic of collaboration between net-
works of people who freely organize around a common goal using
shared resources, and market-oriented entities that add value on top of
or alongside them. Prominent cases of commons-based peer production,
such as the free and open-source software and Wikipedia, inaugurate
a new model of value creation, dierent from both markets and rms.
The creative energy of autonomous individuals, organized in distributed
networks, produces meaningful projects, largely without traditional
hierarchical organization or, quite often, nancial compensation.
This represents both challenges and opportunities for traditional
models of cooperativism, which date back to the nineteenth century,
and which have often tended to gradually adopt competitive mentali-
ties. In general, cooperatives are not creating, protecting, or producing
commons, and they usually function under the patent and copyright
164
system. Further, they may tend to self-enclose around their local or
national membership. As a result, the global arena is left open to be
dominated by large corporations. Arguably, these characteristics have
to be changed, and they can be changed today.
The concept of open cooperativism has been conceived as an eort
to infuse cooperatives with the basic principles of commons-based peer
production. Pat Conaty and David Bollier have called for “a new sort of
synthesis or synergy between the emerging peer production and com-
mons movement on the one hand, and growing, innovative elements of
the cooperative and solidarity economy movements on the other.” To a
greater degree than traditional cooperatives, open cooperatives are statu-
torily oriented toward the common good. This could be understood as
extending, not replacing, the seventh cooperative principle of concern for
community. For instance, open cooperatives internalize negative exter-
nalities; adopt multi-stakeholder governance models; contribute to the
creation of immaterial and material commons; and are socially and politi-
cally organized around global concerns, even if they produce locally.
We will outline a list of six interrelated strategies for post-
corporate entrepreneurial coalitions and a mode of value creation that is
autonomous, fair, and sustainable. The aim is to go beyond the classical
corporate paradigm, and its extractive prot-maximizing practices, toward
the establishment of open cooperatives that cultivate a commons-oriented,
ethical economy.
First, it’s important to recognize that closed business models are
based on articial scarcity. Though knowledge can be shared easily
and at very low marginal cost when it is in digital form, closed rms
use articial scarcity to extract rents from the creation or use of digi-
tized knowledge. Through legal repression or technological sabotage,
naturally shareable goods are made articially scarce so that extra
prots may be generated. This is particularly galling in the context
of life-saving medicines or planet-regenerating technological knowl-
edge. Open cooperatives, in comparison, recognize natural abundance
and refuse to generate revenue by making abundant resources arti-
cially scarce.
165
Second, a typical commons-based peer production project involves
various distributed tasks, to which individuals can freely contribute. For
instance, in open software projects, participants contribute code, create
designs, maintain the websites, translate text, co-develop the marketing
strategy, and oer support to users. Salaries based on a xed job description
may not be the most appropriate way to reward those that contribute to
such processes. Open co-ops, therefore, practice open-value accounting or
contributory accounting. The Sensorica project, which produces scientic
instruments, expects contributors to log their contributions and, after peer
evaluation, they are assigned a certain amount of “karma points.” Any
income the contributions generate then ow to contributors according
to the points they accrued. This model is an antidote to the tendency in
many rms for just a few well-placed contributors to capture the value that
has been co-created by a much larger community.
Third, open cooperatives can secure fair distribution and bene-
t-sharing of commonly created value through “CopyFair” licenses.
Existing copyleft licenses—such as Creative Commons and the GNU
General Public Licenseallow anyone to reuse the necessary knowledge
commons on the condition that changes and improvements are added to
that same commons. That framework, however, fails to encourage reci-
procity for commercial use of the commons, or to foster a level playing
eld for ethical enterprises. These shortcomings can be met through
CopyFair licenses that allow for sharing while also expecting reciprocity.
For example, the FairShares Association uses a Creative Commons
non-commercial license for the general public, but allows members of its
organization to use the content commercially.
Fourth, open cooperatives are able to make use of open designs to
produce sustainable goods and services. For-prot enterprises often aim
to achieve planned obsolescence in products that would wear out pre-
maturely. In that way, they would maintain tension between supply and
demand and maximize their prots; obsolescence is a feature, not a bug.
In contrast, open design communities, such as these of the Wikispeed
car, the Wikihouse, and the RepRap 3D printer, do not have the same
incentives, so the practice of planned obsolescence is alien to them.
166
Fifth, and relatedly, open cooperatives reduce waste. The lack of
transparency and penchant for antagonism among closed enterprises
means they will have a hard time creating a circular economy—one
in which the output of one production process is used as an input for
another. But open cooperatives can create ecosystems of collaboration
through open supply chains. These chains can enhance the transpar-
ency of the production processes and enable participants to adapt their
behavior based on the knowledge available in the network. There is
no need for overproduction once the realities of the network become
common knowledge. Open cooperatives can then move beyond an
exclusive reliance on imperfect market price signals and toward mutual
coordination of production, thanks to the combination of open supply
chains and open-book accounting.
Sixth, open cooperatives can mutualize not only digital infra-
structures but also physical ones. The misnamed “sharing economy” of
Airbnb and Uber, despite all the justied critique it receives, illustrates
the potential in matching idle resources with demand. Co-working,
skill-sharing, and ride-sharing are examples of the many ways in which
we can reuse and share resources. With co-ownership and co-govern-
ance, a genuine sharing economy could achieve considerable advances
in more ecient resource use, especially with the aid of shared data
facilities and manufacturing tools.
How, then, does the concept of platform cooperativism relate to
the notion of open cooperativism? Cooperative ownership of platforms
can begin to reorient the platform economy around a commons-ori-
ented model. We highlighted six practices that are already emerging in
various forms but need to be more universally integrated. We believe
that a chief ambition of fostering a more commons-centric economy
is to recapture surplus value, which is now feeding speculative capital,
and re-invest it in the development of open, ethical productive com-
munities. Otherwise, the potential of commons-based peer production
will remain underdeveloped and subservient to the dominant system.
Platform cooperatives must not merely replicate false scarcities and
unnecessary waste; they must become open.
PART 4
CONDITIONS OF
POSSIBILITY
169
SHOWCASE 2 : ECOSYSTEM
The “killer apps” of plaorm capitalism didn’t come out of nowhere.
The big companies that rule the Internet aren’t coming to dominate
just because of a good idea and a charismac founder; they grow out
of supporve ecosystems, including investors, lawyers, sympathec
governments, and tech schools. Perhaps most important is their cul-
ture—the fesvals, the meetups, the memes, the manifestos—that
share norms for what kinds of pracces are expected and celebrated.
To change these norms, we need to culvate an ecosystem for plat-
form cooperavism. These projects demonstrate that this eort is
already under way.
170
Project Name: Loomio Cooperave Ltd.
Completed by: Mary Jo Kaplan
Locaon: Wellington, New Zealand, and Providence, Rhode Island
URL: loomio.org
Loomio is a worker-owned cooperave that is building a tool for
collaborave decision-making used by thousands of cooperaves, com-
munity organizaons, social movements, and government iniaves
across the globe. Loomio enables people to contribute to decisions
that aect them, to drive self-determinaon, beer decisions, stronger
communies, and engaged workplaces. Loomio’s users are incredibly
diverse and so are the ways they use the tool, from day-to-day oper-
aonal decisions in companies, to collaborave policy development in
government, and community engagement by NGOs. In late 2015 we
released Loomio 1.0, a mobile-rst interface with a focus on interop-
erability and an automated subscripon system designed for growth.
Loomio is a robust social enterprise with an ethical business model
that was started four years ago. As a worker-owned cooperave, Loomio
is owned collecvely by the people building it. The current board of
directors is made up of four members and one former member. As an
open source tool and global social enterprise, we acvely engage devel-
opers, contractors, acvists, investors, customers, advisors, and other
stakeholders to work with us to make a beer product and company.
We’ve aracted talented people to work well below market rates
without issuing tradional equity. We bootstrapped for four years
through consulng revenue, loans, crowdfunding, grants, and dona-
ons. Also, we’ve aracted extremely valuable advisors by being gen-
uinely mission-driven. In November 2015 we raised $450,000, using
redeemable preference shares as an investment instrument that
aligns with our social mission and cooperave structure while pro-
viding a fair return to investors.
Loomio is poised for growth in the second half of 2016 and beyond.
Our vision is for Loomio to be a ubiquitous technology, seamlessly inte-
grated with other tools people use every day. By growing revenues
based on providing value to our customers, not selling user data or
adversing, our success will be based on serving customers’ needs and
realizing workers’ collecve values and commitment to social impact.
171
Project Name: The FairShares Model
Completed by: Rory Ridley-Du
Locaon: Sheeld, England
URL: fairshares.coop
The FairShares Model is a suite of intellectual properes devel-
oped during social enterprise research programs at Sheeld Business
School in order to support the creaon and development of solidarity
cooperaves. The working assumpon is that the exclusion of primary
stakeholders from enterprise ownership and governance harms the
well-being of members and their host community. The associaons
model rules encourage four classes of membership: founders, labor,
users, and investors.
FairShares IP is owned by the member(s) who contribute to it.
Members license it to the FairShares Associaon for use in charitable
and commercial projects. If members leave, both they and the asso-
ciaon retain non-exclusive licences. Policy decisions are taken by
members. Decisions on markeng are usually taken by members and
supporters in a Community Forum (on Loomio.org). Members com-
municate with supporters and each other via MailChimp, Facebook,
and Loomio.
FairShares IP is freely available in PDF format from fairshares
.coop (with editable versions that can be supplied directly by email
or through a shared Dropbox). Supporters can join a MailChimp list,
make regular nancial contribuons, and join the Community Forum
at fairshares-associaon.com. Some help is provided free at the
point of use or via Loomio discussion boards, and some members
oer paid consultancy services.
A 2015 survey showed that FairShares IP is being acvely used in thir-
teen countries including the United Kingdom, the United States, Australia,
and New Zealand, and has global reach through its inclusion in a social
enterprise textbook. Clients in the United Kingdom, the United States,
and Ireland created FairShares enterprises in 2015, and we are sup-
porng new projects in Australia and Croaa. We currently have 1,629
subscribers on MailChimp, 885 followers on Facebook, 69 supporters in
our Community Forum, plus 11 labor, 6 user, and 4 founder members.
172
Project Name: Swarm Alliance
Completed by: Joel Dietz
Locaon: Palo Alto, California
URL: swarmalliance.com
Swarm Alliance is a network of aligned organizaons that are
dedicated to creang a world of abundance. We’ve been especially
involved in the world of collaborave governance and the commons.
Most of the technology developed through our network has involved
blockchain in some fashion.
The Swarm Alliance uses the Distributed Collaborave
Organizaon model that we co-invented at a legal conference at
Harvard University. This model was designed to have two levels, one
for rapid decision making (delegates) and another for approval of
large decisions (members). The Swarm Alliance currently has three
delegates and approximately one thousand members. It is the rst
and largest operaonal example of an organizaon hosted enrely
on a blockchain.
We started with an approximately $1 million crowdfunding cam-
paign around our own blockchain-issued asset, the Swarm coin. Aer
much of the funds were exhausted in the process of our own legal
research and the coin’s price uctuaons, we nanced development
through corporate partnerships. At this point we are re-engineering
our inial proof of concepts (developed on Bitcoin) to release ready
concepts on Ethereum.
We are currently building a global ambassador network through
training events in various cies across the globe. We are also currently
exploring other projects that might bridge to a mainstream audience
and serve as a proof of concepts for both the future of governance
and community abundance. As with our original concept, we expect
new forms of crowdfunding to have a major role in this, especially
around blockchain-hosted organizaons.
173
Project Name: Ms., The Madeline System
Completed by: Eden Schulz and Brendan Marn
Locaon: New York City
URL: hp://theworkingworld.org/us
The Madeline System networks local, cooperave investment
funds, giving them the ability to stay community-controlled and yet
gain the benets of scale. Through pooling the investments of a net-
work of funds, Madeline dramacally increases the market leverage of
each fund and allows it to command far beer investment terms. By
joining the funds into a network of mutual accountability and sharing,
Madeline also brings high-quality business assistance to even the
smallest partners. The result is a distributed, non-extracve nancial
system with communies in the posion of power.
Organizaons using Madeline become members and own their
assets together cooperavely. Decisions are made democracally,
with the governance structure designed to minimize central control
and maximize local autonomy.
The inial development of Madeline was made possible by a gen-
erous donaon. As members become operaonal, they share the cost
of maintaining Madeline using income from their local investments.
Cooperaon is the heart of Madeline, and it is the only way that the
scaled benets of the system can be brought to small loan funds at a
reasonable price-point. Cooperaon is also the key to bringing capital
to small funds at terms paent and low enough to allow the nurturing
of local businesses.
In the past year, we have brought together our rst cohort of
member funds who will form the foundaon of the Madeline user-
member base. Over many years, we have successfully built and used a
prototype of the Madeline plaorm, and we have designed and begun
building the launch version of the system. We expect to begin using
this version with our rst members before the end of 2016. By the end
of 2017, we project a robust network of members using the system
across the country.
174
Project Name: Purpose Fund
Completed by: Alexander Kühl and Armin Steuernagel
Locaon: Berlin, Germany
URL: hp://purpose.ag
Purpose Fund is a startup fund for an ecosystem of purpose-driven
entrepreneurs. The fund invests in companies that have a “purpose
ownership” form, which means that the company owns itself.
There are two basic principles of purpose ownership: (1) vong
rights are decoupled from dividend rights and are held by those who
lead the company or are acvely involved; (2) prots are a means to
an end and not an end in themselves. In pracce this means that divi-
dend rights are held by investors without vong rights. Dividends are
capped and prots are reinvested or used to pay back investors. We
call this the self-determinaon of the company. Because of this own-
ership structure, decisions are not driven by shareholder value maxi-
mizaon, and the company is not an object of speculaon.
Purpose ownership—which can take dierent legal forms,
including cooperaves—is a clear signal to employees, investors, cli-
ents, and other potenal collaborators that their contribuon ben-
ets the purpose of the company rather than the private wealth of
equity holders. This enables close cooperaon between the startups
because they know that the value that is thus created cannot be pri-
vately extracted. Purpose companies voluntarily share employees and
code, creang benets similar to those found in large corporaons
while retaining decentralized ownership.
The fund invests in plaorm tech companies that are working on
the future of work, insurance, the sharing economy, decentralized
internet, and open data. It leaves vong rights with entrepreneurs
and its investment strategy is evergreen rather than exit-driven.
Rooted Internet, itself a self-owned company partly controlled by its
startups, raises money by selling non-vong shares. It promises never
to extract more money out of the startup ecosystem than a certain
capped dividend.
175
Project Name: rCredits
Completed by: William Spademan, Execuve Director of Common
Good Finance
Locaon: Western Massachuses
URL: rCredits.org
The rCredits® system is a complete alternave banking system
for the common good, using a local credit/debit rCard® with incenve
rewards and no fees for buyers or sellers. This system empowers any
community to decide together whats best for them, with money to
fund it, using an innovave parcipatory decision process.
Anyone can open an rCredits account with a member invitaon.
Transacons, decisions, and funding are managed independently and
transparently within each region or community. Every member gets
one vote and can vote directly on any substanve issue.
About three person-years have gone into developing a smart-
phone app and backend server. In addion to that me and eort,
hundreds of private donaons provided about $300,000 to cover thir-
teen years of work. We built a self-funding mechanism into the design,
so as the rCredits system grows, it becomes more and more sustain-
able. For the past year, we have been preparing for growth by auto-
mang administraon of the system and segmenng it by community,
so each community can manage its own aairs. The system includes
protocols for essenal cooperaon and mutual oversight between
rCredits communies.
We now have active rCredits pilot projects in western
Massachuses, southeastern Vermont, and Ann Arbor, Michigan. We
are inving interested individuals in other communies to begin pro-
mong rCredits locally. In April we expect to release a revised rCredits
app that works on both iPhone and Android. The rCredits system has
handled three-quarters of a million dollars in transacons, and we
have freed up tens of thousands of dollars for our parcipang com-
munies to use for grants, incenves, and investments in sustaina-
bility. Our top achievement is the nearly seamless integraon with the
mainstream economy, allowing the system to grow smoothly in order
to provide a democrac, community-centered replacement for our
unjust and destrucve global economic system.
176
Project Name: External Revenue Service
Completed by: Max Dana
Locaon: Brooklyn, New York
URL: externalrevenue.us
The External Revenue Service (ERS) is a peer-to-peer tax system
designed to make it easier for people to share their disposable income
with the things they care about most. The rules of the ERS are simple.
Givers pledge a percentage of their income to be automacally redis-
tributed to a porolio of receivers each month, and receivers must
make a giving pledge of their own in order to receive the funds that
have been pledged to them. In the ERS, everyone is a philanthropist.
The ERS is a distributed collaborave organizaon and is not
owned by anyone. It is a network of contributors and users invested
in the maintenance and development of the system. We currently col-
laborate via an open Slack team that is modeled on similar Slack teams
piloted by OpenBazaar and Backfeed.
We have had the good fortune of having some very smart people
come forward to help dene and rene the vision of the organizaon.
As we transion from concept to product, we are acvely seeking
more developers to contribute to the codebase as well as legal experts
to help us navigate the complex regulatory landscape (parcularly
with respect to digital currencies). Financially, the organizaon is
bootstrapped with a small pool of funding from the community and
is commied to forgoing tradional investment in favor of voluntary
funding from the network.
In May 2015, the ERS was just an idea born out of frustraon with
fundraising and income inequality, but under the mentorship of Gary
Chou at Orbital NYC we were able to validate some early assumpons
and raise money via Kickstarter to bring together a seed community
for the Weird Economics Summit in NYC in November 2015. In 2016,
we hope to develop a minimum viable product of the plaorm and
pilot it in partnership with like-minded organizaons.
177
Project Name: Data Commons Cooperave
Completed by: Noemi Giszpenc
Locaon: Massachuses
URL: datacommons.coop
The Data Commons Cooperave brings together cooperave, sol-
idarity, social, generave, new” economy organizaons that are cat-
aloging or mapping some slice of that space. Many organizaons want
to publicize the existence of alternaves and enhance the connecons
among them; the data-sharing cooperave makes it easier for mem-
bers to gather, share, maintain, display, and deploy informaon about
the economy they care about.
The DCC is owned by its data-sharing members. It is incorporated
in the state of Massachuses and has an elected board of directors.
The bylaws are at member.datacommons.coop/bylaws. Decisions are
consensus or super-majority. The membership raes yearly budget
and capital plans. The board of directors receives membership appli-
caons and votes on accepng new members. Each member chooses
what data to share and how or with whom. When we have permanent
sta, we’ll have a democrac workplace.
Making it work is a struggle. This feels like necessary infrastruc-
ture, but thats about as sexy as paving a road. We’ve had devoted
tech volunteers, and received support from foundaons, donors, and
the government—but, it hasn’t been enough to cross the threshold
into sustainable operaons. Our current plan is to focus on fundraising
and cross-subsidizaon from commercially viable products.
We have thirty members, an elected board of ve representa-
ves, a user-friendly search-and-display codebase (Stone Soup), and
the beginnings of a technical soluon to the directory-updates chal-
lenge (da). We’ve been featured in Grassroots Economic Organizing,
Shareable, and Community-Wealth.org; helped shape a map of the sol-
idarity economy in the United States (solidarityeconomy.us); and will
play a role in shaping a census of co-ops in the Northeast. In the next
few years, we hope to raise enough money to pay sta and provide
more tailored member services.
178
Project Name: Coliga
Completed by: Pedro Jardim
Locaon: Berlin, Germany
URL: coliga.co
Coliga is a plaorm that helps any network create a vercal mar-
ketplace and become more self-organized and nancially sustainable.
We make it easy for networks, like coworking spaces and coopera-
ves, to share in any revenue generated from jobs and connecons
they facilitate for their members.
Many networks have strong local and global brands, and they
regularly receive job requests and oers for their members. Coliga
improves how networks capture and channel these opportunies to
their communies, with tools to nd the best people for the job and
split the value with them once the job is complete. That way value is
created and shared within the network, rather than being taken away.
We’ve structured the ownership of our company in a way that
maximizes our long-term social impact. We’ve separated vong shares
(allocated at nominal value to company managers) from income-
paying shares, which means investors get dividends but not the right
to inuence the business strategy in a way that sacrices purpose in
favor of short-term prots. Our bylaws also dictate that all prots are
to be reinvested into the company.
Coliga is the latest project of people behind Apoio, a self-organ-
ized community cleaning service, and Agora Collecve, a leading crea-
ve space in Berlin. We’re part of the OuiShare community and won a
2015 OuiShare award in the category of collaborave economy. We also
belong to Rooted Internet, which invests in purpose-driven companies. In
the coming years we are going to build a diverse global community of
like-minded peers to enable new forms of collaboraon and resource
sharing among networks.
179
Project Name: CommunityOS: Callicoon Project
Completed by: Ashley Taylor
Locaon: Bushwick, Brooklyn, New York
URL: futureculture.how/community-os-callicoon-project
CommunityOS is a layer in the blockchain operang system. It is a
community network for exchanging resources, creang added value,
and developing cooperaves using complex barter systems and repu-
taon calculators. It will rst be used at scale in the agricultural com-
munity of Sullivan County, New York, for the Callicoon Project, and for
event communies in New York City.
The project collaborates closely with ConsenSys, a blockchain
company developing tools that allow cooperaves to easily form and
manage their resources, make decisions, collaborate, transparently dis-
tribute equity and shares, and evolve themselves. These include board-
room.to (governance and decision making), inekt.us (community net-
work and events), weifund.io (decentralized crowdfunding and equity
distribuon), and uPort.me (cryptographic identy and reputaon con-
tainer). The Inekt plaorm serves as the interface to CommunityOS.
On January 16, 2016, we had a potluck event with interested people
in the Callicoon community at one of the well-known farms. We intro-
duced the ideas of cooperave management and resource banks. We
are currently developing a cooperave model for a red-meat processing
facility. It will include day-to-day management, community investment,
and community insurance, all contractually secured on the blockchain.
We are also building a resource bank that will allow communies
to idenfy, search, exchange, barter, and gi between each other. Our
goal is to develop new metrics for value and new marketplaces to rec-
ognize that value for each community, creang a diverse ecosystem of
community-based support and connecon.
We are currently supported by ConsenSys and simultaneously
applying for grants for the research on the cooperave economic
models that will be prototyped alongside the implementaon of
CommunityOS in context, specically in Callicoon.
180
Project Name: Backfeed
Completed by: Julian
Locaon: Tel Aviv, Israel
URL: backfeed.cc
Backfeed is an engine for decentralized collaboraon. It builds
upon the power of open-source collaboraon and enhances it with
a distributed governance system for decentralized value producon
and distribuon. We’ve developed an algorithm that allows large
groups of users to contribute freely and spontaneously to an enter-
prise, determine the perceived value of each contribuon, and allo-
cate inuence and rewards accordingly. Backfeed makes it possible
for decentralized networks of peers to coordinate themselves indi-
rectly in order to achieve the full potenal of collecve intelligence.
Backfeed is a privately held company founded by Matan Field and
Primavera de Filippi.
Backfeed is currently funded exclusively by angel investments.
We are now raising funds in order to support our operaons. Later
this year, we intend to launch a crowd-sale of Backfeed tokens that
will serve to fuel the Backfeed protocol and plaorm.
We are already at an advanced stage of development of our core
technology—the Backfeed protocol engine—which provides an out-
standing breakthrough in the eld of decentralized collaboraon.
We’ve built an API layer that lets others connect to and operate our
protocol, which is currently used by our partners at Slant News to
enable collaborave eding for arcles on their plaorm. There are
various other companies and organizaons interested in using our
system, and we’re currently establishing partnerships and collabora-
on opportunies with strategic partners and like-minded individuals.
In parallel to that, we are also developing our own app, as a tesng
ground for experiments and for the development of further compo-
nents of the protocol stack.
181
Project Name: My User Agreement
Completed by: Anna Bernasek, D.T. Mongan
Locaon: New York City
URL: myuseragreement.com
Myuseragreement LLC oers individuals terms and condions
intended to protect their legal rights in the data they create. For the
rst me consumers have a real opon; its no longer necessary to
blindly accept unfair terms from service providers. By adopng myus-
eragreement, consumers can protect their rights in just a few easy
steps. Individuals sign up by subming their email, and when we have
reached a stascally signicant number of sign-ups we will go live. At
that point, we send each user an email with a link that allows installa-
on of a simple digital marker alerng anyone interacng with a user’s
device to your terms and condions.
Myuseragreement was founded as a public service in 2015 by
Anna Bernasek and D.T. Mongan, the authors of All You Can Pay:
How Companies Use Our Data to Empty Our Wallets (Naon Books,
2015). Anna Bernasek is a journalist and author based in New York.
Among other publicaons, she has wrien for The New York Times,
Newsweek, Fortune, Time, The Australian Financial Review, and The
Sydney Morning Herald. D.T. Mongan is a lawyer based in New York. He
wrote the terms and condions for myuseragreement. Those terms
and condions are laid out on our website in a simple and straighor-
ward way.
Myusergreement is in the sign-up phase and our focus is on
spreading the word about this new Web tool for consumers. We wel-
come any interest and suggesons from the public. Please be in touch
through the website or with the founders directly. We believe that by
acng together we can develop a beer and safer Internet.
182
29. BEYOND LUXURY
COOPERATIVISM
JOHN DUDA
The long neoliberal revolution in the psychology of advertising made
it possible to mistake the atomized actions of consumers for commit-
ment and authenticity: cool becomes commodity, and the production
of the individual consumer replaces the project of collective liberation.
This process of recuperation—in which individuals realize themselves
primarily in and through the choices they make in the marketplace
can also inltrate our visions of alternatives, with our utopian imagi-
nation all too often already colonized by its own undoing. The success
or failure of platform cooperativism may lie in whether it can escape
becoming absorbed into the consumerist colony.
Neoliberalism’s cultural revolution arguably began in the coun-
terculture of the 1960s, in which opposition to systemic injustice and
alienation found expression in new patterns of life. But choosing to
live dierently could all too easily mean prioritizing a new form of
empowered” consumer identity over collective political engagement.
It’s no coincidence that this historical moment gave rise, on the one
hand, to the early visions of a networked economy, and on the other,
to the rst signicant wave of cooperative development in the post-
WWII period. In both, the individual, reduced to a consumer, stands
in for the collective subject of political action, and alternatives become
spaces of withdrawal, not engagement.
Consider the expansive vision of the Whole Earth Catalog, inviting
the people at the intersection of the thriving counterculture and a nas-
cent cyberculture to take up the “tools” they will need to rebuild
183
Spaceship Earth. The project of liberation, in the Catalog, is quite liter-
ally a shopping exercise: one picks out the ideas and technologies that
construct and conrm a new identity in (nominal) opposition to the
mainstream—hence the mélange of yurts and primitive computers,
cybernetics, and new age theology that oats across its pages. This
early cyberculture shares more than we might expect with the closed
corporate networks of the 1980s—in an infamous CompuServe ad,
we see the way utopian promise feeds on (literally white) fear of urban
spacea retreat from political community into networked consumer
identity. Today’s app-mediated landscape, despite some innovations
in network topology, and a new relationship between economic and
racial privilege and urban geography, oers another iteration of the
same: digital platforms allow us to pick and choose the communities
we connect with and commit to, replacing the messy work of political
solidarity with the frictionlessness of “disruption.
The collective and cooperative workplaces emerging from the
late-1960s counterculture followed the same neoliberal logic. These
alternative institutions were an escape routea way for those with the
requisite privilege to construct bubbles of autonomy, outside the alien-
ating corporate workplace and market. The most prolic and enduring
cooperatives of the era were the various food cooperatives that sprung
up across the country, quite literally built on the idea of aligning con-
sumer choices with new values.
It isn’t that cooperative consumer purchasing can never result
in powerful or inclusive collective institutions—Japan’s Seikatsu
Cooperative, built largely by women and an inuential force in food
policy, shows otherwise. But where Seikatsu is premised around
rejecting “choice” as illusory in favor of a limited set of sustainably
farmed staples, the food co-ops of the 1960s (or at least the ones that
were viable nancially) promoted a mode of opposition to the status
quo mediated by consumer choice. Taking stock of this wave of coop-
eratives in 1979, David Moberg wrote, “Many alternative institutions
were rendered relatively harmless as another market choice.” Much
as the counterculture technologists unwittingly prepared the way for
184
the corporate Internet, the food cooperative movement largely fueled
the commodication of natural and organic food as an upscale market
segment, not the development of a just and sustainable food system.
The budding movement for platform cooperatives should avoid
recapitulating this trajectory. One place to look for guidance can and
should be the current wave of cooperative development, which looks
very dierent from its 1960s and ’70s counterpart, especially when it
comes to worker cooperative development. While the worker cooper-
ative sector remains quite small, the movement to expand it is robust,
dynamic, and incredibly instructive when it comes to thinking about
building a more inclusive economy.
For one thing, the contemporary worker cooperative movement
is a lot less white than most people imagine. The largest worker coop-
erative in the country is the two-thousand-person Cooperative Home
Care Associates in the Bronx, whose worker-owners are overwhelm-
ingly women of color. Strong networks of interlinked worker coop-
eratives are developing in historically marginalized communities of
color across the country—like the house cleaning and food processing
cooperatives incubated by Prospera in Oakland, or the Evergreen
Cooperatives in Cleveland, with worker-owners running a multi-acre
urban greenhouse, a green energy company, and a large-scale com-
mercial laundry. Such developments did not arise automatically, but
resulted from the careful work of organizers, community advocates,
and nonprot developers who have started from the premise that the
point of building worker cooperatives is rst and foremost to create an
economy owned by the people who have been traditionally locked out
or pushed to the side—immigrants, the poor, the formerly incarcer-
ated, and other victims of business as usual.
This kind of shift in focus means leaving behind some of the cher-
ished emphasis that the last cooperative wave put on autonomy and
independence; instead, cooperative developers have been enthusiasti-
cally exploring ways to partner with city governments, labor unions,
forward-thinking philanthropy, and impact investors to create mecha-
nisms to nance and support the work of building a more democratic
185
economy. Cooperative purity can easily become an obstacle to
achieving meaningful scale and inclusive impact. For instance,
insisting that members self-nance their own enterprise risks creating
a closed circle of relative economic privilege rather than a movement
to truly democratize capital. Similarly, insisting on autonomy from
government intervention and support means that the policies behind
traditional economic development will continue to grind away, sub-
sidizing corporations and leaving cooperatives to fend for themselves.
The point, as cooperative advocates have come to realize, is not to
create maximally pure alternatives that help a few escape an alien-
ating system, it’s to take seriously a long-term project of actually trans-
forming what counts as business as usual—in the direction of equity,
democracy, solidarity, and sustainability.
What can a movement for platform cooperativism learn from all
this, then? Perhaps the most crucial lesson is to understand why a deep
commitment to inclusion needs to be a grounding principle, not an
afterthought. In the absence of institutional designs and development
processes that put the needs and aspirations of the marginalized rst,
platform cooperatives might very well create new spaces of exciting
digital freedom for their members, but in so doing only put a new spin
on the existing patterns of inequity.
Part of this involves tackling the question of nancing. Worker-
cooperative developers have been very busy identifying pathways to
scale their eorts by making public, philanthropic, and impact capital
available to new and existing democratic workplaces. Platform coop-
eratives looking to reach a scale comparable to that of the dominant
platforms are going to need to follow the lead of the worker coopera-
tive movement and get creative and intentional about their nancing
strategies.
Similarly, there needs to be a recognition among platform co-op
developers that no matter how good your intentions are or how tech-
nically sophisticated your project might be, market dynamics alone
tend toward inequitable outcomes. Changing this equation means
nding ways to connect cooperative initiatives to resources that
186
aren’t completely constrained by the logic of prot. The Evergreen
Cooperatives, for instance, leverage the procurement dollars of large
place-based nonprots like universities and hospitals to create a par-
tial shelter from the market—building the foundations of a long-term
eort to create worker-owned jobs in severely distressed communities.
Above all, it’s imperative that people drawn to platform cooper-
ativism realize that the smooth space of disruption is not where real
collective power can be built. No matter how shiny its apps or how
ostensibly democratic its process, an institution built on a foundation
of individual privilege to opt in will do nothing to challenge and
transform the underlying dynamics of our economic system. Instead,
we need to look past the mirage of supercial alternatives and get busy
building real relationships across sectors and throughout our commu-
nities. This means committing to investments in deep collective edu-
cation, long-haul transformative organizing, and intentional eorts to
shift resources to and building power in the communities that today’s
economy locks out. While technology might help facilitate this work,
it cannot magically replace it.
187
30. MONEY IS THE ROOT OF
ALL PLATFORMS
BRENDAN MARTIN
To use the term “platform cooperativism” is to sum up an incredible
swath of economic theater in just two words. The term, rst, presumes
the concept of a platform as a common infrastructure people use. But
putting the word “cooperativism” after it is to suggest the central ques-
tion of a platform is who owns it: is it owned cooperatively by all those
who use it, or by just a few who extract value from the rest? I contend
that, despite the great advances in technology that have made Internet-
based platforms explode into our lives, the contest over who owns our
platforms is not at all new. It is, rather, one of the central struggles of
civilization, from the rst wars over the Fertile Crescent to the present
battles about Uber.
Money, or nance, is not just what people use to buy platforms;
it itself is a platform. Finance is the infrastructure of exchange as old
as history, and the battle for its control has been raging since the rst
coins were minted and the rst debts recorded. Finance is so funda-
mental to our economy that we can easily miss it, as a sh may not be
aware of the water it swims in, but we cannot aord to do this. Finance
is not just one of the oldest platforms, it is perhaps the root that so
many other platforms are controlled by. This means that challenging
the structures of nance may be the key to challenging the ownership
of any platform. Recent advances in platform technologies oer new
tools for doing just that.
To put into perspective the role that nance plays in the owner-
ship of other platforms, consider what keeps any of us from making our
188
own Uber or some other large platform. Our attention is focused on
the breakthroughs in technology, like smartphones and the Internet,
that have made these platforms possible. But technology is not the
barrier to making a platform; if anything, the advances in technology
have made platform-building easier. The barrier is nance. How else,
but with mountains of money, could a few unelected menas most
platform owners arecommand hundreds of programmers and thou-
sands of marketers and lawyers to build a platform they alone own
and which millions depend on? It is the platform of nance, and the
intensely unequal control of that platform in our world today, upon
which so many other unequal platforms have been built.
Privately held money is not the only way to build a platform,
however. Platforms have been built through government—such as a
highway system, or an electrical grid, or the Internet itself—and these
are generally controlled (in theory at least) not by investors but by cit-
izens. Platforms can also arise from the spontaneous eorts of people
organized by unions, communities, or movements, such as farmers’
producer cooperatives. But, by and large, the new platforms suddenly
impacting our lives are mainly built on the platform of private nance.
BREAK THE BANK AND LIBERATE THE PLATFORM
It might be tempting to conclude that, given the domination of private
nance in society as a whole, building a cooperative platform would
require something like a revolution. But this is not true, and every
cooperative in the world proves this every day.
Consider a worker-owned factory. In the “standard” inves-
tor-owned factory, finance gets pooled together; it buys the labor
and materials to build and run the factory, it hires and res workers, and
it keeps whatever prot comes in. In a worker cooperative, however, the
workers gather together; they borrow the money to build and operate the
factory, they pay it back when they don’t need it, and they keep whatever
profit comes in. This worker cooperative turns the platform of
189
nance on its head. It was in Mondragon, the great mecca of cooperatives
in northern Spain, that the workers declared that capital must be subor-
dinate to labor to allow cooperatives to ourish. We must do the same if
we want to build platform cooperatives. No plan to build one will make
sense unless control over nance is a key part of its strategy.
The logical conclusion of this is to turn the platform of nance
itself into a cooperative. Then, each new cooperative enterprise would
not turn into a struggle to resist centralized nance, but cooperatives
could be built repeatedly on their shared platform of cooperative
nance.
Mondragon built its cooperative nancial platform the
old-fashioned way: the members made a brick-and-mortar bank,
the Caja Laboral, put all their personal and corporate savings into
it, and built it into a nancial powerhouse over decades. Upon this,
they built an extraordinarily expansive and vibrant cooperative
economy that has impacted their entire region and turned a tiny
mountain village into the headquarters for many multi-billion-dollar
worker-owned businesses.
We can follow Mondragon’s example and build institutions that
directly compete with centrally owned nance. This is what credit
unions, public banks, and cooperative lenders like my organization,
The Working World, have been doing for a long time. But the struggle
to gain ground against the U.S. nancial system is much harder than in
the isolated village of Mondragon in the 1950s. So far, the promise of
nancial cooperativism for all remains a very uphill battle.
This is where the disruptive power of technology could become
an opportunity. The Internet’s capacity for enabling transactions
among disparate people, for sharing information about products and
investments, and for creating new currencies and decentralized means
of exchangeeach of these creates opportunities to subvert traditional
nance. We have a window for taking advantage of them, and this is
exactly what The Working World and our allies are trying to do. (For
more about this eort, see our showcase on The Madeleine System in
this book.)
190
THE GUERRILLA WAR OF PLATFORM COOPERATIVES
Cooperative businesses have managed to succeed in a world of central-
ized nance, and cooperative platforms can too, but it isn’t always easy.
Here are some lessons that we at The Working World have learned in
our experience supporting cooperatives, both online and o.
1. Build on cooperative nance. Most cooperatives start with
pools of money from people and communities. In this way, coopera-
tive businesses carve out a bit of cooperative nance to build them-
selves on, and any would-be cooperative platform builder will have to
do the same.
If you imagine getting nancing for a platform, consider the
relationship being oered to you by those who control the nance.
Is it extractive? Will ownership, control, or rewards mostly go to
the sources of money? What if things go at all wrong, and you can’t
meet your targets or make a payment—do you lose control? Resist
the seduction of larger oers of money that come with extractive
strings.
Look for cooperative lenders, credit unions, or CDFIs. Find
impact investors, community investors, or crowdfunding opportuni-
ties. But don’t assume these sources mean you don’t have to pay atten-
tion; structure your deals to make sure the people most involved—the
workers or users—are the owners and nance is the element that gets
hired or red.
2. Don’t just buildconvert. If you need to own a house, do
you always need to build a new one? It is usually much easier to nd
an existing house and buy it—or, to put it another way, convert who
owns it. The problem with many of our platforms is also simply who
owns them, and we may nd it is far easier to make cooperatives,
including platform cooperatives, by converting existing businesses
rather than building them from scratch.
It is predicted that a million protable small businesses will close
in the next decade because their baby-boomer owners are retiring. A
growing body of entrepreneurs and policymakers is looking to save
191
these business by selling them to their workers, thereby converting
them to worker ownership.
There is no reason why we cannot consider conversion for online
platforms as well, although many of them have become so overvalued
that the nancial barriers are considerable. It probably won’t be pos-
sible to buy the biggest companies at the peak of their market value,
but opportunities to change the equation exist. What if the users
aka, content-creatorsof Facebook organized to demand ownership
under threat of a strike? What if municipalities trying to fend o Uber
allowed it to operate in exchange for some form of ownership for
drivers? What if governments and organized groups of people acted
in concert to depress a platforms market value to a price we would be
able to pay? We could start by going after a platform most susceptible
to this type of pressure, converting it to cooperative ownership, and
making it an example for future conversions.
This is certainly not an easy strategy, but it might be easier than
trying to build and nance a massive platform from scratch.
3. Organize. That brings me to my nal recommendation in the
guerrilla war against centralized platforms: organizing.
The practice of social-justice organizing is evolving these days.
Rather than mostly combating businesses and demanding conces-
sions, organizers and the organized are learning to create and control
businesses. The work of organizingsurprisingly to somedevelops
many of the skills needed in a functioning business: communication,
understanding the needs of others, and leading others toward common
goals. Organizing is not the opposite of business, it is just the opposite
of business for the benet of a few. When attempting to build not just a
cooperative business but a cooperative platform, the ability to organize
large numbers of people becomes perhaps the central skill necessary
for success.
In the eort to oppose centralized platforms, now is a time not
just to ght, but to create. The most fundamental challenge may be to
rebuild the underlying platform of nance itself.
192
31. FROM PEOPLE-CENTERED
IDEAS TO PEOPLE-POWERED
CAPITAL
CARMEN ROJAS
As we begin to realize the promises of platform cooperativism, the
challenge we face is not a lack of imagination or of ideas for gen-
erative enterprises. We also don’t lack people who are motivated to
create platforms, networks, or products for what we need to become
better, more complete, and deeply loving human beings. We don’t
lack leaders, doers, technologists, or organizers. What we often think
we lack is capital. But this doesn’t need to be the case, and there is no
time like the present to prove that the resources exist to make platform
cooperativism real.
I speak from experience. I work for The Workers Lab, a labor-
backed innovation lab focused on supporting and investing in
organizers and entrepreneurs to create enterprises that have the
promise to build power for working people. We recognize that the
United States has become a low-wage nation where millions of
workers invest hours into jobs with little hope of meeting their
basic needs. The result has been a social and economic crisis marked
most distinctly by the meltdown of 2008. We believe that workers
should be able to thrive and play an active role in our economy and
democracy. We’ve even learned some lessons about how to make
this happen.
193
THE STATE OF PLAY
There is a perceived mismatch between ideas and capital in the conver-
sations surrounding platform cooperativism. Many people have great
ideas for creating platforms that promise to powerfully connect people
with what they need. But they often struggle with testing their ideas
or developing a prototype because they don’t know where to nd the
capital necessary to shift from ideation to creation.
I would argue there are two reasons for this perceived mismatch
between ideas and capital. The rst is that well-meaning technologists
and entrepreneurs often are not connected with those who might want
to use, adopt, and own their platforms. This leads to the creation of
boutique solutions distant from the people who would most benet
and most likely pay for their existence. If there were a closer connec-
tion between the creators and the potential users, there would be more
ways to resource, create, and validate platforms.
The second reason for the perceived mismatch between capital
and ideas is not unrelated to the rst: the expectation of somehow
obtaining traditional capital resources to support work that ultimately
challenges the existing system. Instead, we need to tap into a radical
imagination that starts to undo the alignments of power that dominate
the nancial landscape. To do so, we should begin with ourselves.
WHO IS THE “WE”?
The creators of platforms and their end users are usually very dierent.
Most people today who are exploring the creation of platforms co-ops
are still white men who have few to no relationships with those they
would like to see governing and owning the platforms they are creating.
If they’re serious about considering their users as true members and
partners, the perceived capital mismatch is actually a customer mismatch.
This reminds me of an experience we had at The Workers Lab. A
young white entrepreneur had created a platform to connect recently
194
trained truckers with quality jobs with benets. Still new to the world
of investing, we were anxious to prioritize employers’ needs over
those of workers, based on an unspoken assumption that any job was
better than no job. We approached the entrepreneur, and he was easily
swayed to refocus his business to meet the demands of employers, as
opposed to persisting in his ambition to connect skilled workers to
quality jobs that they could validate.
This is not an uncommon story. The promise of platform coop-
erativism is to create something new, where those who are most mar-
ginalized and exploited on traditional platforms have another place to
go. But the allure of old-fashioned capital can close that door before
it even opens.
A number of leaders have recognized this mismatch and are
working tirelessly to address it head-on—for instance, the creation of
a training, monitoring, and certication enterprise by the Workers
Defense Project in Austin, Texas. After organizing for ten years to
address the rampant exploitation and lack of protection among immi-
grant workers in Texas’ construction industry, it created a business
where immigrant workers are both the providers and beneciaries of
safety training, can act as on-site monitors, and have co-created the
terms to certify construction projects. By investing in communities of
color and immigrant communities to act as leaders within their busi-
ness, they are demonstrating that the “we” of this work can look like
the “we” of the world.
WHOSE MONEY?
It is possible that we could end up creating platforms that are owned by
the users without truly aligning them with our values. True alignment
means aligning the enterprise with the capital that drives it.
At The Workers Lab, we’ve seen a number of reasons for the dif-
culties that people have in creating bridges between their ideas and
the resources they need. For one thing, those of us who see ourselves
195
working on the side of justice have often become convinced that cap-
ital can’t be a positive tool in this quest. We’ve heard this time and time
again from the kind of organizer who is meanwhile funded by major
foundations, which are subsidized by the state as nonprots. Despite
the contradictions involved, eschewing capital has become a matter of
activist identity.
Others, meanwhile, expect that the same sources of capital that
back exploitative platforms should or would fund their more coop-
erative work. This prospect is not only unlikely, it is also destructive.
Such an approach reduces our expectations to changing the rules of the
game without changing the game itself.
At The Workers Lab, we are looking to marry our ambitions of
platform cooperativism with cooperativist nance. The Securities
and Exchange Commission has enacted new rules on crowdfunding,
through the JOBS Act, that are opening up the ways that everyday
people can invest in the companies that best align with their values.
These new rules allow non-accredited investors to invest, and they also
allow for investments to occur without the intervention of brokers. It
has become easier, in this way, for us to be responsive to the people we
hope to serve and partner with.
Of course, these rules will also allow for the creation of and
investment in more exploitative platforms. But our ability to expose
those who are using this opening for those purposes can be addressed
by organizing and exposing the bad actors. Doing so will help align
us with our collective worries and dreams. When we are the ones
investing in us, new kinds of change are possible.
As we look back at the movement for platform cooperativism
years from now, my hope is that we will see a moment that stemmed
the surge of platforms that exploited working people, devalued human
well-being, and placed prots over all else. My hope is that we will
have created alternatives that became the norms for how platforms
could be used, owned, and shared. My hope is that we will also have,
more broadly, reset the terms of capital and creation for our world.
196
32. CAN CODE SCHOOLS GO
COOPERATIVE?
KAREN GREGORY
As public universities continue to weather attacks on funding and on
their curriculums, the phrase “learn to code” has become something of
a mantra in higher education. It is as though uttering the words to stu-
dents might be a cure-all for what ails the current job market. Across
the United States, public universities are currently struggling to revise
and revamp curriculums in the face of the infamous “skills gap”– a gap
that is presumed to exist between what college students currently learn
and what skills are required in the market. Despite evidence that such
gap claims are overblown, the narrative and rhetoric of the skills gap,
which banks on a feeling that university curriculums have not kept
pace with advances in digital technologies, has nonetheless become
a powerful weapon in the assault against the public university. Yet,
while much ink has been spilled over the value of learning to code,
the conversation seems to miss a fundamental issue: learning to code is
often entangled in a larger privatizing, entrepreneurial mission. If we
stand any hope for an equitable digital future, we will need to situate
a new gure of labor at the heart of learning to code. We will need a
new gure of labor working to design and develop digital platforms.
Yet, while public universities struggle to nd their place in the
emerging higher education economy, a new entity has emerged on the
scenethat of the code school, which oers an independent, stand-
alone set of intensive programming courses to students. I would like to
argue that we can learn a lesson from these code schools, but we can do
them one better. We can bring such projects into the public university
197
as a way to teach new forms of cooperativism, as well as contextualize
such digital work in the larger story of labor history.
Code schools, such as General Assembly, which is a global pro-
vider of intensive digital skills courses, currently oer courses such
as a twelve-week “full-time career accelerator” training program in
Android development. They do this at an additional cost to an indi-
vidual student, as code schools currently stand apart from the tra-
ditional liberal arts students. The schools explicitly link coding and
career. Udacity even goes so far as to guarantee job placement to stu-
dents in their machine learning courses. If students do not land a job
after they complete the course, they are entitled to a refund on the cost
of the course. Rather starkly, Udacity’s founder Sebastian Thrun has
been quoted as saying, “The ultimate objective of education is to nd
people a job.
Code schools strike a chord and they capitalize on a relatively
recent social development—the emergence of the educated underem-
ployed or unemployed. Code schools are able to prot from a relatively
well-educated pool of potential students who are now job seekers in a
depressed market and who are willing to pay out of pocket for addi-
tional skills. In many ways, the existence of the code school legiti-
mately raises the question of what “skills” colleges and universities
should be imparting to students. If code is to be our shared lingua
franca in an increasingly digital and connected world, then more of us
will need to learn to speak in its vernaculars not only in order to “get
to work” but to continue the necessary project of critical, theoretical
scholarship. Coding or programming skills need not be counterpoised
to the work of thought, despite the insistence of some in Silicon Valley.
Yet what interests me here is not debating the merits of learning
to code. What interests me, rather, is the social gure of the private
(and entrepreneurial) laborer who is often brought into being by such
coding projects, particularly when such projects are brought into the
public university and sold back to administrators as a way to embolden
their curricular oerings and recruit students. When the code school
returns to the public university, perhaps as a “coding boot camp” or
198
a “startup incubator,” it is with the explicit expectation that students
will be taught how to be entrepreneurs—how to embrace and identify
with an entrepreneurial model of work and with an expectation that
private risk and debt will eventually be rewarded with the riches of
the entrepreneurial digital market. Yet if the educational context and
conditions of learning to code simply rearm the privatization of risk
and debt, then what expectations can we have that the digital world
will reect more than prot interests? Furthermore, such an emphasis
on entrepreneurialism threatens to duplicate the known gendered and
racial biases and structural inequalities that already plague the digital
economy.
As long as the context of learning to code or program requires
an embrace of the heroic gure of the lone, privatized individual, the
digital world will continue to be built in its image—it will continue to
reify the very notion that the digital economy is a site of “ownership”
and “reward” rather than collective, shared, and public resources.
While the language of digital “making” has entered the univer-
sity, it has come with a curious disinterest in labor and labor history,
which, for all practical purposes, have been radically abandoned in the
contemporary university. Yet, as the university continues to grasp at
entrepreneurial straws, it overlooks an opportunity to reconnect public
higher education to the (rather unknown) future of work. While
coding may sound like a solution to current market woes, in truth, it
will only delay the eventual degradation of such digital labor. When
everyone can code, those jobs too will go the way of other forms of
workoutsourced, undervalued, underpaid, or automated. However,
a digital skills curriculum anchored in labor theory and labor histo-
rya curriculum that explores the possibilities of new forms of col-
lectivities, organizing, and worker agency—has the potential not only
to generate a new app or platform, but to recongure how digital labor
is brought into being and how we imagine continuing to live in and
through digital platforms, networks, and infrastructures.
Such a digital skills program could be built in and through working
with institutes such as the Murphy Institute at the City University
199
of New York. Students would be introduced to a broader world of
labor organizing, cooperative structures, community rights, and labor
politics as they also learn to design, develop, and program. It is also
essential that such a program be designed in and through the public
university as it is precisely public university students, such as CUNY
students, who currently stand very little chance of entering into the
elite world of Silicon Valley. A cooperative code school would not only
help to resituate the public university as a vital tie between students
and the failing job market, but it stands to oer a chance to rethink the
social demographics of digital labor.
Code schools and their ilk are emerging at this time because
they are responding to a need for a trained workforce, but they are
succeeding because they tap into the very real sense that the labor
market in the United States, even for the highly educated, is broken.
As coding projects return to the public university in the guise of entre-
preneurialism, we are losing a valuable opportunity to rethink how
digital “skills” might become a fertile ground for a new, potentially
cooperative-based, labor consciousness. It is time to bring labor history
back to the classroom so that students may begin to rethink technology
and infrastructure in order to build a more equitable world.
200
33. A CODE FOR GOOD WORK
PALAK SHAH
Once every few generations we have a momentous opportunity to
make big changes, to reset norms and culture and to reinvent our-
selves. Thats why the emerging platform cooperativism movement—
as an opportunity to create an economic system that is empathetic
and ecient, a system that solves for equity—is an exciting and rad-
ical development. As we embark upon building these new models,
dening our core values can provide useful guidance to the emergence
of a new economic system.
The essence of platform cooperativism is a rejection of uneven
extraction and an emphasis on cooperativism. This movement is
rightly asking: Who are we problem-solving for? What is the impact
of the new economy on the workers who are the engine that drives
it? Will the new economy be more or less equitable than the old
economy? Will there be more empathy in the new economy? Will
the new economy work for all of us, or is it an online version of the
economy that worked for just a few?
At the National Domestic Workers Alliance, we already know
what it looks like when the economy optimizes for some of us and
extracts value from the least visible of us. We’ve been working on pro-
moting respect and dignity for some of our most invisible and under-
valued workers in the oine economy for years, and what we’ve heard
from these workers about the online economy echoes those injustices.
Workers in the on-demand economy tell us that they like the ex-
ibility of their work, but they fear being cut o from their platforms
without warning after they have to cancel a shift to care for a sick
201
child. Many workers like the economic possibilities of these emerging
sources of revenue, but instead found themselves being paid less than
minimum wage to clean a completely trashed house.
So far, we have little evidence that Silicon Valley will build an
online economy optimized for equity and dignity. While new plat-
form technology presents us with entirely novel ways of organizing
and working together, and a strategic opportunity to reimagine our
economic relationships to one another, the tech businesses have largely
focused on enriching investors’ returns and delighting customers, often
at the expense of the workers who power these platforms. Algorithms
can handily resolve supply and demand imbalances or competing cus-
tomer preferences, but the ruthless pressure to pursue growth and prot
still overpowers the moral case of treating workers well, limiting how
equitable these models can be. While our technological advances can
make life easier for all humans—isn’t that the point of technology?—it
is not yet clear that we will use it to design an economic system that
works for all of us.
What would it mean to build platforms that go further than e-
ciency, style, or convenience? How would we integrate compassion,
dignity, or fairness? How would we write algorithms that optimize
how we treat one another, how we truly connect, and how we sustain
the very people that sustain us? How do we write that into operational
code?
It’s important that we ask these questions, but it’s vital that we
answer them. A political agreement on collective ownership or ide-
ological agreements on worker power can be the rst, essential step.
But the real work is in building models that pick up where commercial
platforms have left o. That means we must roll up our sleeves and dive
into the operational details and inner workings of how labor is distrib-
uted through algorithms, phone-based apps, and online platforms.
This is not as easy as it seems, and there are no shortcuts. The
central task here is to build platforms that can operationalize our com-
mitment to fairness and cooperativism. Why? Because our values alone
wont get us all the way there. Building a cooperative platform is also
202
a pragmatic, operational endeavor, and the devil is in the details of
seemingly unglamorous and mundane processes.
In many areas of business, technology, and even manufacturing,
organizations rely on certain agreed-upon standards to establish a set
of common operating assumptions describing what the system should
do—not necessarily how the system should do it. Whether youre
talking about platform co-ops or Silicon Valley giants, we believe a
set of values-based specs for the new economy could serve as a guide
to embedding dignity and respect into all operations areasa Good
Work Code for the new economy.
Our Good Work Code is a set of eight simple principles that can
serve as a framework, a guide ensuring that the new platforms are
creating good work:
Safety: Good work does not allow for us to wonder at the start
of a shift if we will be unharmed by the end. Everyone deserves to be
safe at work, always.
Stability & Flexibility: Good work is made possible when we
are not anxious about meeting life demands, whether it’s making an
unexpected doctor’s appointment or making enough money to pay
the bills. We are all at our best when our schedules allow us to balance
work and life with a stable—but exibleschedule.
Transparency: Good work means being transparent about
requirements, performance, and the rules. When everyone knows how
things work, everything works better.
Shared Prosperity: Good work rewards all of us. Workers are
the engine powering the platform, and when the platform thrives, they
should thrive too.
A Livable Wage: Good work provides a living. That’s why
we workto live. Everyone needs fair pay and benets to make a
living.
Inclusion & Input: Good work recognizes that our value extends
beyond performing a task. Platforms are more successful when we are
heard, respected, and valued as part of the team.
203
Support & Connection: We all work better when we don’t feel
isolated and alone. Good work supports us to adapt and manage in a
rapidly changing environment and economy.
Growth & Development: Good work provides opportunity for
the most fundamental human need: to grow. Everyone wants to grow
and learn at work as they do in other areas of their life.
The Good Work Code doesn’t introduce any revolutionary new
values. It doesn’t innovate or disrupt previous thinking on good work
standards. But this framework, or a derivative of it, will be essential to
building an equitable platform. We are at the exact right moment in
time to insert this framework into the DNA of the new economy, to
correct the course so that we’re building a new economy that works
for all of us.
With the emergence of the platform economy, we have one of
those rare opportunities to reset the norms and culture of work. At
its best, technology strengthens our humanity and our connected-
ness. We shape our economy as much as it shapes us, and we have an
opportunity to make sure the digital revolution is supported by a long-
overdue revolution in values.
204
34. MEET YOUR FRIENDLY
NEIGHBORHOOD TECH
CO-OP
MICKY METTS
When I joined a web-development tech co-op, it changed my life in
wonderful ways. I am now able to bring my whole self to my work
and have a life that is not divided between work and play. My drive
and passion come from doing what I lovebuilding community, and
enabling people to have the technical tools they need to maintain and
control their autonomy.
It is rapidly becoming easier for someone with a great idea to build
a company online without much of a barrier to entry. Websites can be
set up for free or minimal cost, and cloud services with online website
building tools are plentiful. But sophisticated, cutting-edge platforms
still require skilled people to build them. A new generation of plat-
form co-ops will need developers who understand both technology
and cooperative enterprise. Nobody is better prepared for this work
than tech co-ops.
What, you might ask, is the dierence between tech co-ops and
platform co-ops? How might they collaborate?
Tech co-ops are worker-owned development shops that build cus-
tomized tools. Platform co-ops are online tools owned by the people
who use them. They are dierent, but they will both be stronger if
they work together.
As a co-op and as individuals, Agaric is part of the vibrant, global
Drupal community, which maintains and continually improves a free
205
content management system that makes it easier for people to build
websites. Some of Agaric’s projects result in new software that can be
helpful to others, or solutions to challenges that others might be facing.
When this happens, we package the software we create for free distri-
bution, usually on Drupal.org. Supporting people in building websites
that make the world a better place is rewarding, but being able to
package that free software and put it in the hands of others is nothing
short of incredible. We also collaborate with groups such as the M.I.T.
Center for Civic Media to brainstorm and build projects that benet
our neighborhoods.
Agaric is made up of ve people. We are spread around the world,
but we are all working on a level playing eld. Being a cooperative
allows us to govern ourselves through bylaws that we created. Worker-
owners can join by paying a small, monthly investment, of which a
portion can be recovered if they decide to leave. We earn the same
wage each month, and we all have overlapping skills that comple-
ment each other. We take time to teach each other what we learn
and broaden our knowledge through tutorials and collaborations with
other developers. Freelancers can gain a lot by putting their eorts
together and building small cooperative companies that can provide
services to their communities and beyond.
Like other cooperatives, tech co-ops cooperate with each
other. I am part of the Tech Co-op Network, which lists more
than twenty-five tech co-ops as members on our website,
TechWorker.coop. We have a mailing list where members can post
messages. We share information about our projects, and ask each other
for advice or links to resources such as example bylaws. The group is
a good source for recommendations on governance and details of how
successful cooperatives are structured. The list is also populated with
people who are not yet part of co-ops, but would like to form or join
one. It provides an informal introduction to cooperative business and
makes it easy to ask questions and stay informed.
Being part of a cooperative allows the members to have a voice
and bring projects to the group. When one of our own presented a
206
sound proposal, we started Agaric Nicaragua, a project to build a
resource for developers in Managua to learn programming skills and
to be trained to take on development roles with clients. This is a win
for developers in Nicaragua and for Agaric, to grow talent in areas that
are underserved by local educational opportunities around the world.
We will extend this opportunity to the world by sharing the template
for this project.
This kind of collaboration is essential. Creating a cooperative
internet will require more than just new technology. It will no doubt
take the combined eorts of many tech co-ops to build a new eco-
system of cooperative platforms. The structures and processes we use
to work together must also change from hierarchical, linear forms to
non-linear, cooperative ones. To give a sense of what that entails, here
are some steps for starting a tech co-op of your own:
1. Find the right people. You will need to nd coworkers in your
industry that value working on a one-worker-one-vote basis. Talk
to people in your personal network about your goal. Let former
coworkers know you are forming or seeking to work in a cooper-
ative. Reach out to mailing lists you are on and ask if people are
interested in working collectively.
2. Explore dierent strategies for self-management. Learn
about your local cooperative community. If possible, go to events
where you can meet members of cooperatives (tech or other-
wise) and ask them how their organizations are structured inter-
nally. Most cooperative members are approachable and willing to
answer your questions. Ask them what they think works and what
doesn’t.
3. Consider conversion. This can be easier than starting from
scratch. If you work for a company you like that is not a cooper-
ative, talk to the owners about the possibility of selling it to the
workers.
4. Dene the parameters of your cooperative environment.
Whether through your articles of organization, bylaws, or a simple
207
contractual agreement, be clear about how your cooperative will
work. Above all, a cooperative is dened by its members.
5. Join a cooperative network (or two). For those in North
America, consider the U.S. Federation of Worker Cooperatives
and the Tech Co-op Network. Wherever you are, connect with
whatever kinds of co-ops exist in your area. If there isn’t already a
directory of local co-ops, consider starting one!
6. Invest in other cooperatives. Buy locally whenever you can.
Encourage pooled funds from successful cooperatives to help
bootstrap new proposed cooperatives. When you invest in new
local cooperatives you are investing in your community. Agaric
often collaborates with other co-ops, and we share our leads with
a pool of developers that we have worked on projects with in the
past. Once you have a healthy network, word-of-mouth referrals
go both ways.
7. Choose free tools to run the business. Free software is soft-
ware that can be used, studied, modied, and redistributed by
anyone, for any purpose. Using free software to run your cooper-
ative is not only a way to preserve your freedom, but it will allow
you to share your successes with others by sharing your code. We
recommend free software tools like GnuCash for accounting
because it doesn’t require you to trust a corporate cloud service. If
you think of ways to improve it, also, you can get involved with
the actual development if you choose to make changes. At Agaric,
we believe that cooperativism and free software go hand in hand.
Through steps like this, we really can make our own jobs, manage
our own time, and create our own online platforms through coopera-
tion. Co-ops can teach communities how to be freer from oppressive
systems by being role models. But we must be wise in how we do
it. Strong tech co-ops will make for stronger cooperative platforms.
Co-ops must work together in solidarity.
208
35. BUILDING THE PEOPLES
OWNERSHIP ECONOMY
THROUGH UNION CO-OPS
MICHAEL PECK
Cooperatives and unions started out their organized lives together.
In gritty Northwest England, during the Industrial Age’s heyday—
Manchester in the 1840s—the Rochdale Society of Equitable Pioneers
composed their Rochdale Principles, which became the foundation of
the modern cooperative movement. It was in this same region, around
the same time, that industrial labor unions were beginning to ourish.
Since then, diverging histories, experiences, and destinies have caused
cooperatives and unions to run along mostly autarchic paths, some-
times parallel, too infrequently connecting. Now, as we nd ourselves
in a period of the highest landlord absenteeism since America’s Gilded
Age, it’s time to bring unionism and cooperativism back together.
Americas inequality epidemic calls out for a new labor-
cooperative convergence to accelerate the end of the era of false
structural choices. Yesterday’s Hobbesian, “either-or” menu, forcing
workers to choose between sustaining jobs or a clean environment, or
between racial justice and secure employment, is being replaced with
a more positive and uplifting “all of the above”often through online
platforms facilitating better choices and stronger, more inclusive advocacy.
Compartmentalized hierarchies are breaking down into a more egali-
tarian digital commons, overcoming imbalances between labor and capital.
Emerging communities of freelancers are exhibiting what Sara Horowitz,
founder of the Freelancers Union, calls the “New Mutualism.
209
Increasingly, these new pioneers prefer to own their labor and rent
their capital whenever possible, instead of Wall Street’s predatory opposite.
With less than 10 percent of Americans currently owning their own busi-
nesses and workplaces, today’s “new, new organizing” begins to address
the skewed imbalances between capital and labor and the power this dis-
tortion produces and exercises. Movements and policies are seeking
to extend the “sharing economy” into an ownership-enabler, and
to resist manipulative downgrades into a rental economy, where labor
becomes even more of a bottom-traded commodity without equity benets.
Yesterday’s Davos-sanctioned global marketplace for labor arbi-
trage is becoming unmasked as a cabal for corporatist buying and
selling of human beings and a contributor to global inequality, with
the excuse that labor is a disposable commodity instead of a precious
resource. This turnaround is long overdue.
Starting in the spring of 2014, 1worker1vote.org set out to demon-
strate that widespread workplace equity and democratic participation
can return America to its original system of individual and local com-
munity ownership. This initiative emerged from the historic 2009
United Steelworkers collaboration with Mondragon in the Basque
region of Spain, the worlds largest network of worker cooperatives.
We’re now developing a nationwide cadre of unionized, worker-
owned-and-managed cooperatives to overcome domestic structural
(racial, gender, geographic) inequalities of opportunity, mobility,
and income. A growing multitude of like-minded local and national
organizations are working with us to help existing businesses transition
to a union co-op structure and to launch new union co-op businesses.
Our threefold intent is to:
1. Defeat embedded structural inequalities by deploying tested and
proven hybrid ownership models (starting with the union/co-op
template);
2. Build and launch protable, worker-owned-and-managed enter-
prises in the context of inter-cooperating ecosystems, drawing on
sixty years of the Mondragon experience;
210
3. Co-design projects and tools that can replicate and scale (the com-
plete 1worker1vote.org mantra is: “include, design, build, launch,
replicate, and scale”).
As a clear case in point, and after almost eight years of struggle and
action, Abdi Buni, the president of Denver’s Green Taxi Cooperative,
and Lisa Bolton, now the Communications Workers of America’s
international vice president for telecommunications and technologies
(but previously president of CWA Local 7777 in Denver), have earned
the right to claim success. As a result of their determined “learning by
doing” process and teamwork, unionized and employee-owned cab
companies will dominate the taxi marketplace in Denver.
This represents a remarkable example of how solidarity-
centric business structures can combine with determined union policy
advocacy and market-available technology to produce more holistic
business models. Green Taxi Cooperative has more than eight hun-
dred worker-owners, who are also CWA members, with a newly
signed collective bargaining agreement. Before this, CWA Local 7777
had assisted another local taxi cooperative, the two-hundred-driver
Union Taxi, which is presently not unionized, and the union learned
a lot from that process during round two.
Green Taxi is joining other taxi drivers in New York City and
elsewhere who are launching apps to step up the competition with
Uber, allowing customers to hail a cab and pay for it with their devices
of choice. The platform cooperativism movement is poised to combine
local solidarity structures with open-source technology, transforming
the Green Taxi precedent into a repeatable and scalable economic
opportunity nationwide.
These opportunities are even greater now that the California
Labor Commission has ruled that Uber drivers are employees, not
independent contractors. In more and more jurisdictions, app-based
drivers are winning the right to form a union. This makes it even
easier to align platform cooperativism with the might of organized
labor in the transportation sector.
211
Other emerging economic networks are beginning to aggregate
as well. The Freelancers Union, headquartered in Brooklyn, is the
nations largest labor organization representing the new, independent
workforce of 260,000 members in more than twenty U.S. citiesas
well as the 53 million Americans freelancing today, more than one in
every three workers. In four years, the American Sustainable Business
Council, based in Washington, DC, has become the nation’s fastest
growing private sector trade association of over 250,000 businesses and
325,000 business leaders focused on building a sustainable economy
based on triple-bottom-line principles: people, planet, and prot.
These inter-cooperating communities are forging private and non-
prot solutions in which enlightened government is a minority partner
but not a market-maker.
We can start to see rsthand how new hybrid models such as
union-cooperatives can place worker ownership in the economy’s
center ring, enabled by technology. The online “commons” can rein-
vigorate the American Town Square and Main Street, beneting
from strong antecedents. Historically, marginalized communities
such as African Americans in the Deep Souths agricultural counties
were cooperative pioneers because, as in the churches, they had their
own spaces to democratically organize. Meanwhile, people in racially
and economically conictive zones such as Ferguson, Baltimore, and
Detroit are rediscovering that to secure their civil rights, they must
also secure local equity and ownership.
Research demonstrates that positive employee and company
performance over time correlates with high-impact participation on
all levels by workers, combined with the broadest possible equity
distribution among workers and a strong emphasis on worker edu-
cation. Employees with some form of worker ownership accumu-
late more savings than employees in non-participating rms. Firms
with some form of capital-sharing perform better in the competi-
tive marketplace than those without. Workers with prot-sharing or
employee stock-ownership and stock-purchase plans are better paid
and have more benets than other workers. These kinds of rms also
212
weather economic downturns better than their investor-controlled
counterparts.
Despite this evidence, the so-called American Dream of wide-
spread ownership is receding for a rapidly diminishing and resentful
middle class. But grass, as Pete Seeger sang, still grows through con-
crete. Enabling workers to become owners in their projects and com-
panies reects core American values of freedom, individual dignity,
self-reliance, bootstrapping, solidarity, and equal opportunity—all
reinforced by productive ownership principles and practices. These
ineluctable, hope-instilling values promise an economy that gushes
up rather than trickles down, an economy that is not rented, tithed,
leased, outsourced, or o-shoredan economy in which every par-
ticipant, every worker, has a voice, a vote, and a right to share and
participate in the common good.
213
36. TOWARD A THEORY
OF VALUE FOR PLATFORM
COOPERATIVES
MAYO FUSTER MORELL
Collaboration through online platforms does not happen inde-
pendently of their design and governance. Whether or not they are
thriving depends on platform ownership. Such ownership might con-
dition how well a particular platform can trigger participation and
community interactions, and yet it has rarely been investigated. When
was the last time you heard someone ask about platform ownership?
The Platform Cooperativism event at The New School in 2015
did focus on ownership, but even there quantitative analysis of plat-
form data was largely missing. With regard to user engagement and
value creation, does cooperative ownership really make such a big dif-
ference to corporate ownership?
This chapter draws on research from the P2Pvalue.eu project,
which investigates the conditions that favor value creation in the con-
text of commons-based peer production. Our analysis, which examines
three hundred European organizations, cannot claim to be represent-
ative, due the fact that we cannot account for the entirety of the very
diverse universe of commons production. We did, however, at least
try to represent the heterogeneity of the eld—from free, libre, open
source software (FLOSS), and open data, to open design and open
hardware. Our results are freely available at directory.p2pvalue.eu.
Commons-based peer production refers to a set of activities
characterized by collaborative production, involving peer-to-peer
214
relationships and a resulting common resource. This model stands in
stark contrast to traditional, hierarchical command relationships. It
relies on access to open commons resources—favoring access, repro-
ducibility, and emulation. Some of the best-known examples are
Linux, Wikipedia, OpenStreetMap, and SETI. Commons-based peer
production is not identical with platform cooperativism, but our study
is relevant to the larger platform co-op ecosystem, which is deeply
reliant on commons-related practices.
For a community of commons-based peer producers to operate,
there needs to be a platform—made possible by the people who create
it, maintain it, and facilitate its legal framework. Notably, there are
dierent types of platform providers. Wikipedia, for instance, is facili-
tated by the Wikimedia Foundation, a nonprot foundation steered by
the Wikipedia community. In other cases, however, the platform pro-
vider is a corporation, which leads to far less conducive conditions for
the community. One example is Flickr, the photo- and video-hosting
site owned by Yahoo.
In our research, we identied four types of platform providers: public
institutions; corporations; nonprot organizations such as foundations,
associations, and cooperatives; and informal grassroots organizations that
may not have any legal status. Among the communities we studied, 7.2
percent relied on public institutions, 29 percent relied on corporations, 57
percent relied on cooperatives, and 6.8 percent chose grassroots organiza-
tions or community networks as their platform provider.
GOVERNANCE OF COMMON PRODUCTION
Studies of commons-based peer production have usually investigated
specic, isolated features linked to the governance of such production.
In contrast, we adopt a holistic perspective to understanding the con-
trol and direction of a platform, as well as the distribution of power.
We considered the following six interrelated factors as determinants
and drivers of commons governance:
215
Mission. It really matters who denes the mission of a platform.
Depending on whether it is members of the community or corporate
owners, the platform will develop in accordance with the initial mis-
sion statement.
Management of contributions. This refers to the extent to
which participants are able to decide their own level of commitment,
whether they can dene their contributions based on their personal
interests, motivations, resources, and abilities, and whether relation-
ships are peer-to-peer in contrast to traditional forms of hierarchical
command. Greater exibility of participants seems to be conducive to
higher degrees of contribution.
Decision-making with regard to community interaction.
Governance of commons production depends on decision-making bodies
that also address conict resolution. Consensus-based decision making is
frequent in commons-based peer production but the methods dier.
Formal policies applied to community interaction. As it
evolves, commons-based production tends to establish formal rules
that may be restricting. Such rules include the terms of use and
intellectual-property licenses.
Design of the platform. Individuals are rarely involved in direct
dialogue or negotiations among themselves. Instead, they interact with
the platform design, which steers their participation and interaction.
Therefore, the design must follow the social norms of commons-based
peer production.
Platform provision. We noticed two main axes of platform pro-
vision: open versus closed with regard to community involvement, and
user autonomy versus dependency. A platform is considered open when
participation in the provider space is possible for anyone. Participation
in these cases is regulated through self-selection. For participants,
autonomy is linked to the license held for the commons-pool resources
and the type of software used for the platform (i.e., copyleft licenses
and the use of freely available code, as in FLOSS, versus conditions
dened by ordinary copyright). If the platform can be replicated—if
it is “forkable”—the relationships created on forked versions are free
216
from the original platform provider. FLOSS and copyleft licensing
allow platforms to be replicated, while close copyright license regimes
prohibit that. In other words, the use of FLOSS and a copyleft license
creates conditions in which the community can have greater autonomy
and freedom from the platform provider.
Governance very much depends on who is in control of these six
power nodes in commons production. Each of the axes of governance
can be managed in an inclusive or exclusive way. They may encourage
involvement on the basis of participants as individuals or through the
community as a whole.
The emerging varieties of governance for commons-based peer pro-
duction are highly complex. We found that specically cooperative own-
ership leads to more self-governance among all involved and a more hori-
zontal relational structure; it favors a more peer-to-peer oriented process.
VALUE PRODUCTION FOR COOPERATIVE MODELS OF
PRODUCTION
Studies of commons-based peer production have not produced a con-
solidated analytical framework to assess the value that is produced. One
fundamental challenge for the development of such a theory of value
is the inadequacy of monetary metrics as proxies for value production,
since part of what peer producers create, exchange, and consume does
not pass through monetary exchanges. Thus, as part of our project,
we are developing our own conceptual framework that identies six
dimensions to assess and measure value:
1. Community building
2. Social use-value of the resource created
3. Reputation
4. Achievement of the stated mission
5. Monetary value
6. Ecological value and derivative processes
217
GOVERNANCE AND VALUE
Does the type of platform provision—that is, platform cooperativism
versus platform capitalism—aect the collaborative community’s
capacity to generate value? We found that cooperative structures have
a positive impact on value creation in terms of use-value and repu-
tation. The cooperatives ranked better on web-based use value and
reputation value indicators (such as Google PageRank and the global
Alexa ranking), and performed less well on reputation value indicators
linked to social networks reputation (such as Kred, which is linked to
Twitter, and likes on Facebook). Nevertheless, our analysis didn’t nd
any signicant correlation on monetary value, capacity to achieve its
mission, or capacity to build community.
This is a preliminary analysis that we will elaborate further as
part of the ongoing P2Pvalue.eu research project, but a few things
are clear. What we have shown so far is that platform ownership
models do not only determine governance but also inuence the
capacity to generate value. This should be considered when peers
or policy makers decide what kinds of platforms they are going to
build or promote. According to our analysis, platform cooperativism
will further not only self-governing processes but also the capacity
for people to create resources and services that garner a good online
reputation.
218
37. PUBLIC POLICIES FOR
DIGITAL SOVEREIGNTY
FRANCESCA BRIA
The scale of the transition to platform capitalism is massive. The builders
of emerging online platforms aim to become pervasive across all pro-
ductive sectors, and to permeate every level of society: the level of the
individual (with smartphones and wearable technology, lenses, glasses);
the level of the home (“smart homes,” smart power meters and Internet-
connected sensors); and the level of “smart cities” (driverless cars, net-
worked transportation services; energy grids, drones, ubiquitous digital
services). Platforms are reshaping not just the Internet but the economy
as a whole, and governments have a responsibility to ensure that this new
economy serves more than the platform-builders’ prots.
We are seeing a shift of power, for instance, from service interme-
diaries to information intermediaries, a kind of “Uberization” of ser-
vices. The current data-driven platforms are marketplaces that match
potential customers to anything and anyone. They are able to gather
lots of data, lower transaction and coordination costs, and provide
cheaper services using a dynamic pricing strategy. Most platforms are
monopolies, quickly capturing network externalities by exploiting the
network eect and the economies of scale of their ecosystem. They
are also parasitic, since they free-ride on collective data and people’s
existing social and economic relations. The strategy of these powerful
algorithmic institutions is to enter a variety of economic sectors rapidly
and disrupt current industries. By controlling their digital ecosystems,
they can turn everything into a productive asset, and every transaction
can become an auction where they set the bidding and pricing rules.
219
Platforms are also increasingly transforming the labor market. Uber,
for instance, does not own cars and doesn’t employ drivers; it regards its
workers as independent contractors. In this way, the company external-
izes most costs to workers, eliminating collective bargaining and imple-
menting intrusive data-driven mechanisms of reputation and rankings to
reduce transaction costs (for the company). The growth of the sharing
economy has so far come with an increasing precarization of labor, and
erosion of job security, social protection, and safety nets for workers, such
as benets related to healthcare, pensions, parenting, and so on.
If you are European like myself, and youre used to a functioning,
social-democratic safety net, what is now promised by companies like
Uber and Airbnb is not very appealing. Despite their optimistic pitch
of delivering better and cheaper solutions to solve the world’s greatest
problems—from climate change to health and education—the welfare
program oered by Silicon Valley comes with public services cuts, aus-
terity policy, nancialization of public infrastructure, increasing debt,
and a free license for tech corporations to monitor citizens twenty-four
hours a day.
Many would argue that the European welfare model is no longer
suitable or sustainable. However, there are historical and political rea-
sons that got us to the current situation. Governments forced to imple-
ment counterproductive austerity measures are left with no budget to
invest into social policies.
A common rationale used in defense of the platform economy
is that it will generate a huge wealth for the platform owners, and
they will reinvest these prots into the real economy, thus serving
the public good. Unfortunately, this is not the case. On the contrary,
the latest wave of digital innovation has resulted in excessive returns
to capital, with massive amounts of cash going to the balance sheets
and the oshore accounts of big tech companies, while very little gets
invested in welfare, social infrastructures, education, health, and clean
energy to ght climate change. This situation is exacerbated by the
apparent inability of governments to tax prots made by high-tech and
nancial giants, as seen recently in the very generous tax settlement
220
between Google and the UK government and the tax dispute between
the Italian government and Apple.
THE SHIFT TOWARD DEMOCRATIC,
COMMONS-BASED CITIES
The search for alternatives to platform capitalism should be put within
a broader framework of growing discontent with austerity measures
and the corporatization of everything. In Europe we have very good
examples of movements advocating for the collective management
of public resources such as water, air, and electricity. These represent
potential alliances when we discuss cooperative platforms.
A very interesting example of a city that is putting forward alter-
native policies and forward-looking regulations is Barcelona. After
the large mobilization of the 15M movement beginning in 2011, the
anti-eviction housing activist Ada Colau, a leader in the Platform for
People Aected by Mortgages (PAH), became the mayor of Barcelona,
representing the main political opposition against the elite who
brought Spain into a deep nancial and social crisis, which left hun-
dreds of thousands of families without a home.
The new coalition led by Colau has been crowdfunded and organ-
ized through an online collaborative platform that aggregates policy input
from thousands of citizens. Soon after taking oce, the coalition mem-
bers embarked on a series of radical social reforms. In particular, they
started to enforce regulations to block illegal tourism. The council froze
new licenses for hotels and other tourist accommodations, promising to
ne rms like Airbnb and Booking.com if they marketed apartments
without being on the local tourism register. Barcelona then provided
these companies the possibility to negotiate 80 percent of the penalty if
they allow the Social Emergency Housing Consortium to allocate empty
apartments to residents with subsidized rent for three years.
The city has called for a popular assembly for responsible tourism
where citizens can discuss best practices and business models. The
221
new government is also promoting new policies to foster a
collaborative economy that generates social benefits locally.
Besides these types of initiatives, Ada Colau has also promised a shift
toward re-municipalization of infrastructure and public services.
This is grounded in a very critical understanding of the neoliberal,
surveillance-driven “smart city” model being promoted by big tech
corporations. The ambition, instead, is for a shift to a democratic, green,
and commons-based digital city built from bottom up.
This vision of re-municipalization of critical public services and
network infrastructures is of growing global appeal, leading to a new
alliance between public utilities and cooperative online platforms. A
number of cities and regions across the world are attempting to put
water supply, waste disposal, and energy provision contracts back into
public hands, prioritizing community interests over private commer-
cial objectives. An important innovation has been the growth of new
forms of public utility ownership, combined with more decentralized
forms of collective ownership—including cooperatives with shares
held jointly by the local authorities, labor unions, and citizens.
COOPERATIVE DATA PLATFORMS AND ALTERNATIVE
MODELS FOR DEMOCRATIC INNOVATION
We need public investment in future data-intensive infrastructure and
welfare systems for the common good. Cities and governments have
not yet fully grasped that power lies, today, at the level of data. Only
recently have we begun to view online platforms as meta-utilities,
with the information layer feeding all other services, rapidly changing
the way services are managed and delivered. Data, identity, and rep-
utation are critical in the platform economy. Silicon Valley aspires to
turn data into a new asset class—a commodity to be sold and traded
in nancial markets, with property regimes surrounding it. Shoshana
Zubo of Harvard Business School calls this new reality “surveillance
capitalism.” We have to move from surveillance capitalism to a system
222
that is able to socialize data—such as with new forms of cooperativism
and democratic social innovation.
Cities, for instance, should be able to run distributed common
data infrastructure on their own, with systems that ensure the secu-
rity, privacy, and sovereignty of citizens’ data. Cities can then invite
local companies, cooperatives, civil society organizations, and tech
entrepreneurs to come in and oer innovative services on top of that
infrastructure. One example is the European Commission’s CAPS
program, which has invested around €60 million on collaborative and
open platforms to pilot bottom-up, citizen-led projects with strong
social impact such as the D-CENT project (http://dcentproject.eu),
developing distributed and privacy-aware tools for direct democracy
and cryptocurrencies for economic empowerment. Initiatives like
these can help ensure that the data produced by platforms, devices,
sensors, and software doesn’t get locked down in corporate silos, but
becomes available for the public good. Investing public resources for
piloting innovative, cooperative platforms is necessary to enable cred-
ible alternatives to the current data paradigms exploited by the domi-
nant platforms—integrating economy, technology, society, and policy,
which would otherwise remain fragmented and lead to market con-
centration and regulatory breakdowns.
The current predatory paradigm is not the only solution. We
can harness the technology-driven transformation now under way to
improve our society and welfare for the collective benet. Building
alternative forms of public and common ownership for data-intensive
platforms will help to create an economy that transcends the logic of
short-termism and rent extraction. We are not going to be able to
improve welfare, health, youth employment, education, and the envi-
ronment by leaving the market to do it on its own. We should look
beyond immediate commercial gain in favor of long-term value crea-
tion for society. Twenty-rst century democracy depends on this task.
223
38. LEGAL AND GOVERNANCE
STRUCTURES BUILT TO
SHARE
MIRIAM A. CHERRY
To date, the dominant economic narrative for the gig economy has
been one in which platform owners extract a share of the income gener-
ated from the workers who use their platforms. This is troubling, since
many forms of crowd-work are situated at the crossroads of precarious
work, automatic management, deskilling, and low wages. Recent law-
suits by workers in the gig economy claiming employee status contain
the demand for better pay, hours, benets, and working conditions.
However, these misclassication lawsuits do not seek to change the
ways in which the underlying business relationship between workers
and platforms are structured.
Platform cooperatives, however, subvert the dominant economic
narrative. If workers themselves owned the platforms, then workers
would have control over important matters such as wages and benets.
Cooperatives could clear a path toward ecient and convenient use of
technology for consumers that simultaneously incorporated fair labor
standards. For example, taxi drivers in several cities are working on set-
ting up their own driver-owned platform to compete with the popular
Uber app. I want to put this new move toward platform cooperativism
into context with the underlying legal structures and also to discuss
briey the challenges to governance that platforms cooperatives will face.
Worker-owned businesses have long existed in the United States,
although they have been relatively rare and an exception to the default
224
of the traditional for-prot shareholder primacy model. Many advocates
who seek to better the status of so-called shadow (“under the table”)
workers have long advocated for worker-owned businesses through
groups such as worker centers. Why would becoming owners make
sense as opposed to unionizing and acting collectively to bargain with
an employer? With certain endeavors such as home cleaning, day labor,
and home health, there are individual contracts but no one common
employer with whom the workers can bargain collectively. Likewise,
in the gig economy there are many individual customers using the
platforms. As workers continue to struggle in the gig economy, plat-
form cooperatives have emerged as an appealing possible alternative.
On a practical level, what legal tools are available to help those
who are trying to set up platform cooperatives? Some states have ena-
bling statutes that set out tailor-made rules for worker cooperatives.
However, there is no uniform law across the states, and some states have
passed enabling legislation only for consumer cooperatives. California
faced this issue and, in 2015, amended its legislation to make it clear
that both consumers and workers could form cooperative businesses.
That said, even in the absence of a worker cooperative statute, there
are other business entities that could provide the appropriate organi-
zational structure for worker-owned businesses. One good choice of
business entity for a platform cooperative might be the limited liability
company, which combines limited liability with favorable partnership
taxation. LLCs may be centralized and run by a group of managers
(similar to a board of directors in a traditional corporation) or run in a
decentralized way with equal voting, much like our traditional notion
of a general partnership. If the operating agreement is properly struc-
tured so that the workers are made the members of the LLCs and given
management rights, then that should accommodate a worker-owned
business model.
Over ten years ago, in a paper appearing in the UC Davis Law
Review, I noted that business planning techniques (which those who
have access to nancial and accounting resources routinely employ)
could be used to improve the situation of low-wage immigrant women
225
workers. Due to language barriers, immigrant workers often are at
the mercy of the managers who arrange the work. In this scenario,
immigrant workers often work for depressed wages, are paid under the
table, and do not receive benets. In contrast, LLC structures allowed
these same shadow workers to organize and own their own busi-
nesses, hiring an English speaker—at a set wageto work for them,
scheduling and arranging jobs. Within an LLC structure, the workers
are able to decide what benets would best serve their members. In
addition, as worker-owners who are actively engaged in managing
the business and paying taxes, LLC members may have an easier time
regularizing the workers’ immigration status or, at the very least, not
creating a tax liability issue for the workers with the Internal Revenue
Service. Finally, the experience of receiving training, and becoming
knowledgeable in running a business, can assist workers in taking what
otherwise could be seen as a “dead end” low-skilled job and trans-
forming it into a much better opportunity for advancement. Many of
the advantages for low-wage immigrant workers inherent in a work-
er-owned business form could also improve the lot of gig-economy
workers.
Another intriguing and potentially fruitful possibility for organ-
izing platform cooperatives would be for the platform to incorpo-
rate and obtain certication as a B Corporation. B Corporations are
a class of for-prot entities that simultaneously strive to create ben-
ets to the environment, workers, or communities. As such, they
operate as a hybrid, straddling the category of for-prot and non-
prot. B Corporations strive for transparency, and investors in such
rms understand that there may be tradeos—opportunities for prot
that may in fact be passed by in pursuit of social-benet goals. The
B Corporation incentives would harmonize well with worker co-ops
that already have workers’ issues at the very core of their organiza-
tion and mission. They would also resist the type of “mission drift”
of cooperatives that lose their social vision, such as electric co-ops
that continue to use polluting coal. To date, eleven states have passed
enabling legislation to recognize B Corporation status, with additional
226
states passing similar or complementary types of legislation, such as
Californias exible purpose corporation. These business forms put
social benet at the heart of the organization’s mission.
Regardless of the choice of business entity, another important
issue is designing a workable governance structure in the operating
agreement or corporate documents. There are some issues unique to
online platform cooperatives that could present particular challenges
to governance. Some of the issues include accommodating for ex-
ibility and part-time work. One of the main attractions of the gig
economy is exibility. Worker-owners in platform cooperatives may
be working part-time, and there will be a need for ease of entry or
exit. Another issue could arise around the amount of eort workers
contribute. Although one hopes that workers who work for them-
selves and other workers will dedicate themselves to building their
platform, cooperative endeavors could create moral hazard and the risk
of shirking. The other challenge with crowd-work, where the work
can be performed in any geographical location, is that there will be
participants from many dierent countries, each with its own set of
legal rules.
The fact that there are no tailor-made enabling statutes geared
specically toward platform cooperatives contributes to increased
setup costs and barriers to entry. But many businesses that do not t the
traditional mold have had to confront this issue before. Platform coop-
eratives will be eligible to seek out nancial and technical assistance
from the same worker centers and legal services agencies that have
helped set up worker-owned businesses in the past. Others, perhaps
those that seek B Corporation status, may benet from seeking pro
bono legal assistance or accounting advice from for-prot rms that
are looking to give back to the community. The basic legal structures
for platform cooperatives, while not “o the rack,” do exist. They just
require the tailoring that legal and nancial professionals can provide.
Given the turnover and exibility of online platform work, the
operating documents should be written to allow for relative ease of
entry and exit as a member. In addition, the organizing documents
227
must also set up the relationship in a way that sets out what the expec-
tations are for the members, clearly and succinctly. The documents
need to include provisions for reducing the share of prots if an indi-
vidual member is shirking, and also contain clear provisions dening
under what circumstances a member or shareholder may be disasso-
ciated. In terms of the global or international scope of many plat-
forms, the operating agreement and other documents can be written
to provide for choice of law and choice of jurisdiction. Current statutes
allow for electronic or remote voting for boards of directors or mem-
bers, so long as such procedures are set out in the corporate charter or
operating agreement. Note that running a business is riskier for the
individual worker in a platform cooperativelike any business, the
LLC members or B Corporation shareholders run the risk that there
will be no prots.
Perhaps the answer to the misclassication lawsuits and the
struggle over employee status is to work around it, regardless of the
outcome. While not the perfect solution, already-existing legal struc-
tures can be modied to accommodate platform cooperatives.
228
39. BLOCKCHAINS AND THEIR
PITFALLS
RACHEL O’DWYER
A blockchain is essentially a distributed database. The technology rst
appeared in 2009 as the basis of the Bitcoin digital currency system,
but it has potential for doing much, much more—including aiding in
the development of platform cooperatives.
Traditionally, institutions use centralized databases. For example,
when you transfer money using a bank account your bank updates its
ledger to credit and debit accounts accordingly. In this example, there
is one central database and the bank is a trusted intermediary who
manages it. With a blockchain, this record is shared among all partici-
pants in the network. To send bitcoin, for example, an owner publicly
broadcasts a transaction to all participants in the network. Participants
collectively verify that the transaction indeed took place and update
the database accordingly. This record is public, shared by all, and it
cannot be amended.
This distributed database can be used for applications other than
monetary transactions. With the rise of what some are calling “block-
chain 2.0,” the accounting technology underpinning Bitcoin is now
taking on non-monetary applications as diverse as electronic voting,
le tracking, property title management, and the organization of
worker cooperatives. Very quickly, it seems, distributed ledger tech-
nologies have made their way into any project broadly related to social
or political transformation for the left—“put a blockchain on it!
until its mention, sooner or later, looks like the basis for a dangerous
drinking game. On the other side of things, poking fun at blockchain
229
evangelism is now a nerdy pastime, more enjoyable even than ridi-
culing handlebar moustaches and xie bicycles.
So let me show my hand. Im interested in the blockchain (or
blockchain-based technologies) as one tool that, in a very pragmatic
way, could assist with cooperative activities—helping us to share
resources, to arbitrate, adjudicate, disambiguate, and make collective
decisions. Some edgling examples are La’Zooz, an alternative ride-
sharing app; Swarm, a fundraising app; and proposals for the use of dis-
tributed ledgers to manage land ownership or critical infrastructures
like water and energy. Many of these activities are dicult outside
of local communities or in the absence of some trusted intermediary.
However, I also think that much of the current rhetoric around the
blockchain hints at problems with the techno-utopian ideologies that
surround digital activism, and points to the assumptions these projects
fall into time and again. It’s worth addressing these here.
ASSUMPTION #1: WE CAN REPLACE MESSY AND
TIME-CONSUMING SOCIAL PROCESSES WITH
ELEGANT TECHNICAL SOLUTIONS
Fostering and scaling cooperation is really dicult. This is why we
have institutions, norms, laws, and markets. We might not like them,
but these mechanisms allow us to cooperate with others even when
we don’t know and trust them. They help us to make decisions and
to divvy up tasks and to reach consensus. When we take these things
away—when we break them down—it can be very dicult to coop-
erate. Indeed, this is one of the big problems with alternative forms
of organization outside of the state and the market—those that are not
structured by typical modes of governance such as rules, norms, or
pricing. These kinds of structureless collaboration generally only work
at very local kin-communal scales where everybody already knows
and trusts everyone else. In Ireland, for example, there were several
long-term bank strikes in the 1970s. The economy didn’t grind to a
230
halt. Instead, local publicans stepped in and extended credit to their
customers; the debtors were well-known to the publicans, who were
in a good position to make an assessment on their credit worthiness.
Community trust replaced a trustless monetary system. This kind of
local arrangement wouldn’t work in a larger or more atomized com-
munity. It probably wouldn’t work in today’s Ireland because commu-
nity ties are weaker.
Bitcoin caused excitement when it proposed a technical solution to
a problem that previously required a trusted intermediary—money, or,
more specically, the problem of guaranteeing and controlling money
supply and monitoring the repartition of funds on a global scale. It
did this by developing a distributed database that is cryptographically
veried by an entire network of peers and by linking the production
of new money with the individual incentive to maintain this public
repository. More recently this cryptographic database has also been
used to manage laws, contracts, and property. While some of the more
evolved applications involve verifying precious stones and supporting
interbank loans, the proposal is that this database could also be used to
support alternative worker platforms, allowing systems where people
can organize, share, or sell their labor without the need of a central entity
controlling activities and trimming a generous margin o the top.
Here the blockchain replaces a trusted third party such as the state
or a platform with cryptographic proof. This is why hardcore libertar-
ians and anarcho-communists both favor it. But let’s be clear hereit
doesn’t replace all of the functions of an institution, just the function
that allows us to trust in our interactions with others because we trust
in certain judicial and bureaucratic processes. It doesn’t stand in for all
the slow and messy bureaucracy and debate and human processes that
go into building cooperation, and it never will.
The blockchain is what we call a “trustless” architecture. It stands
in for trust in the absence of more traditional mechanisms like social
networks and co-location. It allows cooperation without trust, in other
words—something that is quite dierent from fostering or building
trust. As the founding Bitcoin document details, proof-of-work is not
231
a new form of trust, but the abdication of trust altogether as social
condence and judgment in favor of an algorithmic regulation. With
a blockchain, it maybe doesn’t matter so much whether I believe in or
trust my fellow peers just so long as I trust in the technical eciency of
the protocol. The claim being made is not that we can engineer greater
levels of cooperation or trust in friends, institutions, or governments,
but that we might dispense with social institutions altogether in favor
of an elegant technical solution.
This assumption is naïve, it’s true, but it also betrays a worrying
politicsor rather a drive to replace politics (as debate and dispute and
things that produce connection and dierence) with economics. This is
not just a problem with blockchain evangelism—it’s a core problem with
the ideology of digital activism generally. The blockchain has more in
common with the neoliberal governmentality that produces platform
capitalists like Amazon and Uber and state-market coalitions than any
radical alternative. Seen in this light, the call for blockchains forms part
of a line of informational and administrative technologies such as punch
cards, electronic ledgers, and automated record keeping systems that
work to administrate populations and to make politics disappear.
ASSUMPTION #2: THE TECHNICAL CAN INSTANTIATE
NEW SOCIAL OR POLITICAL PROCESSES
Like a lot of peer-to-peer networks, blockchain applications conate a
technical architecture with a social or political mode of organization.
We can see this kind of ideology at work when the CEO of Bitcoin
Indonesia argues, “In its purest form, blockchain is democracy.” From
this perspective, what makes Uber Uber and La’Zooz La’Zooz comes
down to technical dierences at the level of topology and protocol.
If only we can design the right technical system, in other words, the
right kind of society is not too far behind.
The last decade has shown us that there is no linear-causal rela-
tionship between decentralization in technical systems and egalitarian
232
or equitable practices socially, politically, or economically. This is not
only because it is technologically determinist to assume so, or because
networks involve layers that exhibit contradictory aordances, but also
because there’s zero evidence that features such as decentralization or
structurelessness continue to pose any kind of threat to capitalism. In
fact, horizontality and decentralization—the very characteristics that
peer production prizes so highly—have emerged as an ideal solution to
many of the impasses of liberal economics.
Today, Silicon Valley appropriates so many of the ideas of the
left—anarchism, mobility, and cooperationeven limited forms of
welfare. This can create the sense that technical xes like the block-
chain are part of some broader shift to a post-capitalist society, when
this shift has not taken place. Indeed, the blockchain applications that
are really gaining traction are those developed by large banks in collab-
oration with tech startupsapplications to build private blockchains
for greater asset management or automatic credit clearing between
banks, or to allow cultural industries to combat piracy in a distributed
network and manage the sale and ownership of digital goods more
eciently.
While technical tools such as the blockchain might form part of
a broader artillery for platform cooperativism, we also need to have a
little perspective. We need to nd ways to embrace not only technical
solutions, but also people who have experience in community organ-
izing and methods that foster trust, negotiate hierarchies, and embrace
dierence. Because there is no magic app for platform cooperativism.
And there never will be.
233
40. NON-COOPERATIVISM
ASTRA TAYLOR
Does digital technology make the dream of a fairer, more cooperative
world more possible? I’m not entirely sure that it does. To the contrary,
I think there was just as good a case for cooperative ownership in the
industrial age, and just as many obstacles, though perhaps those obsta-
cles have shape-shifted. We have to take honest stock of these hurdles
and confront them head on if we want to build a movement that has
a chance of truly challenging the economic status quo. Of course the
powerful don’t want us to change things, and they will go to great
lengths to stop us from doing so, whether by employing bureaucracy
or brute force.
If there’s one thing I want to say here it is that I want my cooper-
ativism—platform or otherwiseto be confrontational. I think it has
to be confrontational to really make a dierence. Or, to put it another
way, we need an inside/outside strategy: building cooperative alter-
natives on the margin while challenging the existing structures at the
center. I’d like to see positive cooperative experiments combined with
strategic campaigns of non-cooperation, of resistance to the nancial
system that promotes selshness over solidarity.
By emphasizing the need not just to create alternatives, but also
to confront the powers that be, I’m echoing longstanding concerns. At
least since Beatrice Webb’s The Cooperative Movement in Great Britain,
published in 1891, some trade unionists have criticized cooperatives for
trying to avoid the inevitable necessity of class struggle. After all, even
a giant cooperative network like Mondragon has to make concessions
to globalization; likewise, small, democratically run cooperatives must
234
play by prevailing market rules on some level or close up shop. I’m
sympathetic to the exigencies that lead to such compromises—we all
make them in our own ways. The point, rather, is that cooperatives do
not eortlessly escape the dictates of capitalism, and so they need to be
part of a broader eort to challenge the dominant economic paradigm.
Fostering an oppositional spirit is vital to the cooperative cause.
As we all know, we are building on old ideas here. Platform
cooperativism may be new, but cooperativism isn’t. Workers have
dreamed of getting rid of bosses, running their own businesses,
and creating a more just society since the earliest instances of labor
unrest. In the 1880s, the Knights of Labor represented more than two
hundred industrial cooperatives that they hoped would serve as the
basis for a “cooperative commonwealth.” There is also the rich his-
tory of black cooperative economic development, which is revealed
by Jessica Gordon Nembhard in her excellent book Collective Courage,
with examples ranging from the Colored Farmers’ National Alliance
and Cooperative Union, which had over a million members in the
late 1800s, to the many eorts compiled in W. E. B. Du Bois’s 1907
Economic Co-operation Among Negro Americans. This tradition lives
on through myriad endeavors, including Mississippis Cooperation
Jackson, the Southern Reparations Loan Fund, and the Oakland & the
World Enterprises, a project I’ll return to.
History abounds with rousing examples of cooperative projects,
and almost as many failures. What sabotaged many of these promising
enterprises is lack of access to capital. Workers are more than capable
of running things without the oversight of bosses or investors, but the
cash or credit to purchase equipment and pay for space, machines, and
materials doesn’t grow on trees.
Some might say that digital technology will resolve this
dilemma—you no longer need expensive heavy machinery, you only
need a website—but I’m not so sure. Digital cooperatives cannot mag-
ically sidestep the economic system that provides the perverse incen-
tives shaping the corporate online platforms many of us have problems
with. Getting rid of bosses and shareholders, with their demands for
235
short-term returns, is a big step, but only the rst one. In other words,
the project of creating cooperative enterprises is inseparable from cre-
ating a nancial system that is productive rather than predatory, gen-
erative rather than extractive. This means, in turn, that in addition to
experimenting with alternative models of business and banking, we
also desperately need to transform or reform the existing economic
apparatus.
The dominant paradigm of nance, in addition to putting cooper-
atives at a disadvantage, is what’s driving much of the inequality we see
today. Some insist that the problem is robots eating our jobs, but the
statistics don’t bear that out. The astonishing rise in inequality since
the 1980s can be at least partly attributed to the explosion of salaries in
the nancial sector, which doubled its representation in the top 1 per-
cent of incomes. Another big factor is pay packages for CEOs, which
more than quadrupled at large companies—though presumably this
wont be a problem when cooperatives take over the world.
That’s assuming world conquest is on the agenda, of course. The
tendency to valorize the small, local, and decentralized is something
else I think we should keep debating. Decentralization is not a pan-
acea; it does not necessarily mean distributed power or equitable distri-
bution of wealth. This is something political theorist Wendy Brown is
very insightful about in her book on neoliberalism, Undoing the Demos.
She calls this kind of non-progressive or reactionary decentralization
“devolution,” and its a term I nd quite useful. “Devolved power
and responsibility,” she writes, “are not equivalent to thoroughgoing
decentralization and local empowerment.
Which brings me to one of my nal points. Centralized public
options need to be on the table along with decentralized cooperative
or commons-based ones. We need to think creatively about how they
complement each other and how they can be combined. (Consider
Janelle Orsis proposal for a municipally owned alternative to Airbnb.)
Hybrid models that connect governments and co-ops would be very
much in keeping with the times, as polls show more and more people
warming up to the idea of socialism. Something has shifted in a big
236
way, and cooperative solutions that involve the state should be on the
table.
But ultimately this isnt just a war of ideas; cooperativism demands
we put our principles into practice. I was reminded of this when I
recently spent time with Elaine Brown, who is seventy-two and ran
the Black Panther Party when founding member Huey Newton was
self-exiled in Cuba. In 2013 she founded the aforementioned Oakland
& the World Enterprises, which will eventually be a network of coop-
eratively owned businesses run by and for formerly incarcerated indi-
viduals. These are the people, Brown argues, who really need to own
their jobs, because they have an even harder time nding work than
everyone else. Right now she has a fully functional organic farm in
West Oakland, but she has plans for a cooperatively owned grocery
store, tness center, nail salon, and tech incubator under ve oors
of aordable housing. What does she need to get this plan to the next
level? Capital, of course—though she has raised quite a bit by part-
nering with the city. It’s a good example of the kind of municipal
collaboration I think we need more of.
Elaine told me, in no uncertain terms, that one should never
organize or mobilize around abstract principles. When the Panthers
organized their free breakfast program, they didn’t say, “You have a
right to nutrition”—they fed people (and then the parents of the chil-
dren they fed went and demanded that schools provide meals, because
if the Panthers could do it, certainly the state could too). Likewise, she
doesn’t motivate her project’s farmers with ideological talking points
or treatises on cooperative economics; rather, she allows them to rec-
ognize how much better it is to share in the prosperity created by their
labor and to be treated like true partners.
Doesn’t the same hold true for everyone? Journalists, wouldn’t you
like to not be treated like disposable providers of work-for-hire con-
tent? Programmers, wouldn’t you like to have a say in what you build
and why you build it, and own the fruits of your labor? Professors and
students, wouldn’t you like to have a deeper stake in the educational
institutions where you teach and learn?
237
Those of us who want the concept of platform cooperativism to
spread should take this lesson to heart. We need to make our case
by building and pointing to real examples. We also need to let go of
abstractions and address concrete concerns: How will platform coop-
erativism make people’s lives better? How will it address their real
needs? How will it feed their families? Or make them feel more con-
nected? Or maybe the real questions are: How will it make our lives
better? How will it address our real needs? How will it feed our fami-
lies? How will it make us feel more connected?
Asking and answering such questions will help these important
ideas take root. But we have to remember to ght. Cooperation must
be coupled with non-cooperation—an active resistance that comple-
ments the building of the alternatives we need.
239
CONTRIBUTORS
Michel Bauwens is the founder of the P2P Foundation and partner
with the Commons Strategies Group. In 2014, he was research
director of the FLOK Society project, which produced the rst inte-
grated Commons Transition Plan for the government of Ecuador. His
recent books are Save the World: Towards a Post Capitalist Society with
P2P (with Jean Lievens, in French and Dutch); and Network Society
and Future Scenarios for a Collaborative Economy (with Vasilis Kostakis;
Palgrave Macmillan, 2014).
Yochai Benkler is the Berkman Professor of Entrepreneurial
Legal Studies at Harvard Law School, and faculty co-director of the
Berkman Center for Internet and Society at Harvard University. Since
the 1990s, he has played a role in characterizing the role of information
commons and decentralized collaboration to innovation, information
production, and freedom in the networked economy and society.
David Bollier is an author, activist, blogger, and consultant who
spends a lot of time exploring the commons as a new paradigm of eco-
nomics, politics, and culture. He’s been on this trail for about fteen
years, working with a variety of international and domestic partners.
In 2010, he co-founded the Commons Strategies Group, a consulting
project that works to promote the commons internationally.
Francesca Bria is a Senior Researcher and Advisor on information
and technology policy. She has a PhD on innovation economics from
Imperial College, London, and an MSc on digital economy from the
University of London, Birkbeck. She is the EU Coordinator of the
240
D-CENT project, the biggest European project on direct democracy
and digital currencies. She also leads the DSI project on digital social
innovation in Europe at Nesta Innovation Lab. She has been teaching in
several universities in Europe, and she has advised governments, public
and private organizations, and movements on technology and infor-
mation policy and its political and socioeconomic impact. Francesca is
an advisor for the European Commission on future internet, collective
platforms, and innovation policy.
Susie Cagle is an American journalist and editorial cartoonist whose
work has appeared in The American Prospect, AlterNet, The Awl,
GOOD, and others. Cagle is based in Oakland, California.
David Carroll is an Associate Professor of Media Design at Parsons
School of Design at The New School, former director of the MFA
Design and Technology program, and former co-founder and CEO of
Glossy, an AI brain learning culture through media. His work is situ-
ated at the intersection of art, design, media, culture, policy, science,
and technology, especially in collaboration with peers in engineering,
journalism, publishing, advertising, privacy, psychology, and peda-
gogy. He’s on Twitter @profcarroll.
Miriam A. Cherry is a Professor of Law at St. Louis University and
a member of the American Law Institute. Her work focuses on the
intersection of technology and employment law.
Ra Criscitiello is a Research Coordinator at SEIU-UHW in
Oakland, California, a union of eighty thousand healthcare workers.
She is also a union-side labor attorney. She is building an innova-
tive employment model that collectivizes the employment status of
unionized workers on scale. In the new worker-driven democratic
landscape, her model allows for on-demand labor without compro-
mising traditional union values. Ra is also a surfer, triathlete, and
banjo player.
241
John Duda is the Communications Director at The Democracy
Collaborative, a national research institute developing new strategies
for the democratization of wealth and the reconstruction of commu-
nity in the face of systemic crisis. He lives in Baltimore, where he
is a co-founder of the Red Emmas worker cooperative, and where
he recently completed a PhD project examining the way the idea of
self-organization developed in the sciences of cybernetics and in left
politics.
Marina Gorbis is a futurist and social scientist who serves as exec-
utive director to the Institute for the Future (IFTF), a Silicon Valley
nonprot research and consulting organization. In her seventeen years
with IFTF, Marina has brought a futures perspective to hundreds of
organizations in business, education, government, and philanthropy
to improve innovation capacity, develop strategies, and design new
products and services.
Jessica Gordon Nembhard, political economist and Professor of
Community Justice and Social Economic Development (Africana
Studies, John Jay College CUNY), is author of Collective Courage: A
History of African American Cooperative Economic Thought and Practice (Penn
State University Press, 2014). An aliate scholar with the Centre for
the Study of Co-operatives at the University of Saskatchewan, Gordon
Nembhards memberships include GEO Newsletter, the Southern
Grassroots Economies Project, and the Association of Cooperative
Educators.
Karen Gregory is a Lecturer in Digital Sociology at the University
of Edinburgh. Her work explores the intersection of digital labor,
aect, and contemporary spirituality, with an emphasis on the role of
the laboring body. Karen is a founding member of CUNY Graduate
Center’s Digital Labor Working Group, and her writings have appeared
in Women’s Studies Quarterly, Women and Performance, Visual Studies,
Contexts, The New Inquiry, and DIS Magazine.
242
Seda Gürses is a Postdoctoral Research Associate at the Center for
Information Technology at Princeton University, and an FWO fellow
at the Computer Security and Industrial Cryptography (COSIC)
research group at the University of Leuven in Belgium. She works
on privacy and requirements engineering, privacy enhancing technol-
ogies, and surveillance. Previously, she was a postdoctoral fellow at
the Media, Culture and Communications Department at the NYU
Steinhardt School and at the Information Law Institute at NYU Law
School. She is also a member of the feminist art collective Constant
VZW in Brussels.
Steven Hill is a senior fellow at the New America Foundation and
the Holtzbrinck fellow at the American Academy in Berlin. His latest
book is Raw Deal: How the “Uber Economy” and Runaway Capitalism Are
Screwing American Workers (St. Martin’s, 2015), and his articles, op-eds,
and interviews have appeared in The New York Times, Washington
Post, Atlantic, Nation, Wall Street Journal, Guardian, BBC, Le Monde,
Politico, CNN, C-SPAN, “Democracy Now,” NPR, Salon, Fast
Company, and more. He can be found at www.Steven-Hill.com and @
StevenHill1776.
Melissa Hoover is the founding Executive Director of the Democracy
at Work Institute, which expands the promise of worker ownership to
communities most aected by social and economic inequality. Prior,
she served as Executive Director of the United States Federation of
Worker Cooperatives. Together, this national grassroots membership
organization and think-and-do tank work to build a member-based
movement that reaches a scale that has real impact. Melissa worked for
six years as a cooperative developer with the Arizmendi Association
of Cooperatives, where she assisted in the development of two new
worker-owned bakeries.
Dmytri Kleiner is a software developer and member of the
Telekommunisten art group. His work investigates political economy
243
and the social relations embedded in communications technology. He
is the author of the Telekommunist Manifesto and can be followed at
http://dmytri.info.
Vasilis Kostakis is a tenured Senior Research Fellow at the Ragnar
Nurkse School of Innovation and Governance at Tallinn University
of Technology, Estonia. He is also Founder of the interdiscipli-
nary research hub P2P Lab and Research Coordinator of the P2P
Foundation.
Brendan Martin is founder and president of The Working World.
After studying economics and a stint on Wall Street, Brendan became
focused on the connection of nance and economic justice. In 2004,
he founded TWW in Argentina to work with the recovered factory
movement for economic democracy. Brendan now heads TWW in the
United States, implementing the same principles in a post-industrial
context.
Michele (Micky) Metts is a member of Agaric, a worker-owned
tech cooperative doing web development. She is known as an Activist
Hacker/Industry Organizer/Public Speaker/Connector/Advisor and
Visionary. Micky is the liaison to the Solidarity Economy Network
(SEN) and the United States Federation of Worker Cooperatives
(USFWC). She is a member of FSF.org and Drupal.org, a community
based on free software. Micky grew up in Weston, Connecticut, and
now lives in Boston with her partner, John Crisman.
Kristy Milland is community manager of TurkerNation.com. She’s
been a crowd worker, Requester, and researcher over the last decade.
She speaks about the ethics of crowd work, exposing worker exploitation
caused by a lack of legislation that would protect workers from corporate
interests. She is also engaged in multiple projects to create new platforms,
which will oer fair compensation and other benets to crowd workers,
and wants to join new projects which promise to do the same.
244
Mayo Fuster Morell directs the Dimmons Digital Commons
Research Group at the Internet Interdisciplinary Institute of the Open
University of Catalonia. As part of IGOPnet.cc, she is the principal
investigator of the P2P Value European project on value creation in
collaborative production. She is a Faculty Associate at the Berkman
Klein Center for Internet and Society at Harvard University. She also
directs the expertise group BarCola on collaborative economy, linked
to the Barcelona City Council.
The NYC Real Estate Investment Cooperative (NYC REIC)
was founded in 2015 to leverage the patient investments and polit-
ical power of members to secure permanently aordable commercial
properties in NYC for community, small business, and cultural use.
Consistent with the principles and spirit of the cooperative movement,
the NYC REIC makes long-term, stabilizing, and transformative
investments for the mutual benet of our members and our communi-
ties. Find out more at http://nycreic.org.
Rachel O’Dwyer is a research fellow and lecturer at Trinity
College, Dublin. She is a member of the P2P Foundation and the
IoT Council, and is the curator of Openhere, a festival and con-
ference on the digital commons. She writes about the polit-
ical economy of communications, with a focus on digital
currencies and decentralized networks. She is a regular contributor to
Neural magazine and the founding editor in chief of the open access
peer-reviewed journal Interference. She’s on Twitter @rachelodwyer.
Janelle Orsi is a lawyer, advocate, writer, and cartoonist focused on
cooperatives, the sharing economy, urban agriculture, shared housing,
local currencies, and grassroots nance. She is Co-founder and Executive
Director of the Sustainable Economies Law Center (SELC), which facili-
tates the growth of sustainable and localized economies through education,
research, and advocacy. Janelle is the author of Practicing Law in the Sharing
Economy (ABA, 2014) and co-author of The Sharing Solution (NOLO, 2009).
245
Michael Peck is a co-founder of 1worker1vote.org and serves as
Mondragons North America delegate, an American Sustainable
Business Council board member, a Blue Green Alliance Corporate
Advisory board member, and a MAPA Group founder. 1worker1vote
is a nationwide economic development catalyst, mobilizing the union-
co-op hybrid model reecting Mondragon values of single-class equity
and workplace solidarity democratically practiced in protable enter-
prises to overcome structural inequalities.
Carmen Rojas is the CEO of The Workers Lab, an innovation lab
that invests in entrepreneurs, community organizers, and technologists
to create sustainable and scalable solutions that build power for U.S.
workers.
Douglas Rushko is an author, teacher, and documentarian who
focuses on the ways people, cultures, and institutions create, share,
and inuence each other’s values. He is Professor of Media Theory
and Digital Economics at CUNY/Queens. His new book, Throwing
Rocks at the Google Bus: How Growth Became the Enemy of Prosperity,
argues that digital networks are still capable of fostering a distributed
economy, but only if we can abandon the industrial-age mandate of
growth above all.
Saskia Sassen (www.saskiasassen.com) is the Robert S. Lynd
Professor of Sociology and Member, The Committee on Global
Thought, Columbia University. She is the author of several books and
the recipient of diverse awards and mentions, ranging from multiple
doctor honoris causa to named lectures and various honors lists. Her
new book is Expulsions: Brutality and Complexity in the Global Economy
(Harvard University Press, 2014), which is already translated into thir-
teen languages, with more coming.
Nathan Schneider is a scholar-in-residence of media studies at
the University of Colorado Boulder and co-organized the Platform
246
Cooperativism conference in 2015. His articles have appeared in publi-
cations including VICE, The Nation, The New Republic, The Chronicle of
Higher Education, and YES! Magazine. His two books, God in Proof and
Thank You, Anarchy, were published by University of California Press.
Follow his work at his website, nathanschneider.info.
Trebor Scholz is a scholar-activist and Associate Professor for Culture
& Media at The New School in New York City. His latest book, Uber-
Worked and Underpaid: How Workers Are Disrupting the Digital Economy
(Polity, 2016), develops an analysis of the challenges posed by digital
labor and introduces the concept of platform cooperativism as a way
of joining the peer-to-peer and co-op movements with online labor
markets while insisting on collective ownership and democratic gov-
ernance. His next book will focus on the prospects of the cooperative
Internet. Follow him on Twitter at @trebors.
Juliet Schor is Professor of Sociology at Boston College and a
member of the MacArthur Foundation Connected Learning Research
Network. She is conducting a six-year project on economic inno-
vations, including “sharing” spaces. A bestselling author, Schor has
published books that include The Overworked American, The Overspent
American, and True Wealth: How and Why Millions of Americans Are
Creating a Time-Rich, Ecologically Light, Small-Scale, High-Satisfaction
Economy (previously published as Plenitude).
Palak Shah is the Social Innovations Director of the National
Domestic Workers Alliance, leading experimental and market-based
approaches to improve working conditions, services, and employment
opportunities for online workers. Palak has led NDWAs introduc-
tion into the on-demand economy with the Good Work Code, and
is driving forward the organizations collaboration with Silicon Valley
leaders. Previously, she served as a leader at Wellmont Health System,
as a member of Massachusetts Governor Deval Patricks administra-
tion, and as a consultant at Accenture.
247
Kati Sipp is the Future of Work Campaigns Director for the National
Guestworkers Alliance. She created the blog Hack the Union, which
focuses on the intersections of work, organizing, and technology. She
founded the Pennsylvania aliate of Working Families, and spent
nine years working for SEIU Healthcare Pennsylvania, serving as
the Political Director and Executive Vice President. Kati is the proud
mother of Alina and Isaac. Follow her on Twitter at @katisipp and @
hacktheunion.
Tom Slee writes about technology and politics. His new book, What’s
Yours Is Mine: Against the Sharing Economy, was published by OR Books
in November 2015. He has a PhD in theoretical chemistry, a long
career in the software industry, and his earlier book No One Makes You
Shop at Wal-Mart (BTL, 2006) is a left-wing game-theoretical investi-
gation of individual choice that has been used in university economics,
philosophy, and sociology courses.
Christoph Spehr is a politician, author, and theorist. He worked for
the German National Conference on Internationalism (BUKO), the
cultural co-op Paradox at Bremen, and the Left Party. From 1997 to
2005 he was co-editor of the magazine Alaska, and from 2008 to 2015
he was regional head of the Left Party, Bremen county. He wrote a
theory of Free Cooperation that won the Rosa-Luxemburg-Prize in
2001, and was included in The Art of Free Cooperation (Autonomedia,
2007), along with a DVD including his video On Rules and Monsters.
Danny Spitzberg is a sociologist and user researcher based in Oakland,
California. He is principal at peakagency.co, a collective that partners
with cultural and economic justice projects to build community plat-
forms. He is also helping build seed.coop, a platform for co-ops every-
where to grow their membership. Say hi on Twitter @daspitzberg.
Arun Sundararajan is Professor and the Robert L. and Dale Atkins
Rosen Faculty Fellow at New York University’s Leonard N. Stern
248
School of Business. He is also an aliated faculty member at NYUs
Center for Urban Science+Progress, and at NYUs Center for Data
Science.
Astra Taylor is a documentary lmmaker, writer, and political
organizer. She is the director of the lms Zizek! and Examined Life, and
the author of The People’s Platform: Taking Back Power and Culture in the
Digital Age (Picador, 2015), winner of a 2015 American Book Award.
She helped launch the Rolling Jubilee debt-abolishing campaign and
is a co-founder of the Debt Collective.
Cameron Tonkinwise is the Director of Design Studies and Doctoral
Studies at the School of Design at Carnegie Mellon. Cameron continues
to research what designers can learn from philosophies of making,
material culture studies, and sociologies of technology. Cameron’s
research and teaching focus on the design of systems that lower soci-
etal materials intensity, primarily by decoupling use and ownership: in
other words, systems of shared use.
McKenzie Wark is the author of Molecular Red: Theory for the
Anthropocene (Verso, 2015), among other things, and teaches at The
New School in New York City.
Caroline Woolard’s interdisciplinary work facilitates social imagi-
nation at the intersection of art, design, and political economy. After
co-founding and co-directing resource sharing networks OurGoods
.org and TradeSchool.coop, Woolard is now focused on her work with
BFAMFAPhD.com to raise awareness about the impact of rent, debt,
and precarity on culture, and on the NYC Real Estate Investment
Cooperative to create and support truly aordable commercial space
in New York City.
249
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
The insurgency from which this book stems, together with the book
itself, could only have been possible through remarkable feats of
cooperativism. Throughout this process, we have been awed by the
enthusiasm, creativity, and commitment demonstrated by those who
have come together to help make a more cooperative online economy
a reality. The books contributors, who oered their insights in the
essays and their ingenuity in the showcases, have been inspiring and
patient collaborators. Many other people, too, have helped support this
eort, often in less visible ways.
Micah Sifry was an early adopter of Trebor Scholz’s concept of plat-
form cooperativism, and he, together with his colleague at Civic Hall,
Andrew Rasiej, were a source of ongoing support, advice, and meeting
space. Neal Goreno of Shareable was among the rst to recognize that
a real, cooperative sharing economy was starting to take shape; he helped
guide Nathan Schneider into discovering it for himself. Palak Shah of the
National Domestic Workers Alliance and Sara Horowitz of the Freelancers
Union were among our early conversation partners who helped connect
this work to the challenges workers are facing at the front lines of the
gig economy, as did two courageous worker-organizers on Amazon’s
Mechanical Turk, Rochelle LaPlante and Kristy Milland. Natalie Foster
of Institute for the Future provided invaluable guidance as well.
We are grateful for the support of this unconventional research
project from colleagues at our institutions, especially Dean Stephanie
Browner, Karen Noyes, Alexander Drainger, and Verna De LaMothe
at The New School’s Lang College and, at the University of Colorado
Boulder’s College of Media, Communication, and Information, Dean
Lori Bergen and Nabil Echchaibi.
250
The book itself came about thanks to the willingness of John
Oakes at OR Books to say yes and ask questions later, as well as his
commitment to the challenge of creating righteous models for inde-
pendent publishing in the age of Amazon. And it is only thanks to
the rigor and guidance of Samira Rajabi that we were able to meet a
seemingly impossible self-imposed deadline.
The Platform Cooperativism event in November 2015 was
sponsored by Eugene Lang College The New School for Liberal
Arts, Demand Progress, the Democracy at Work Institute, the Ford
Foundation, the Freelancers Union, IG Metall, the Institute for the
Future, Internet Society, the Lang Student Senate, The New Schools
Digital Humanities Minor, The New School University Student Senate,
the Robert L. Heilbronner Center for Capitalism Studies, University
of Colorado Boulders College of Media, Communication, and
Information, the Rosa Luxemburg Foundation NYC, and the Workers
Lab.
The event was presented in partnership with Carnegie Mellon
School of Design, Civic Hall, Democracy Collaborative, Green
Worker Cooperatives, The Laura Flanders Show, the Murphy Institute
for Worker Education and Labor Studies at CUNY, the New Economy
Coalition, OccupyWallStNYC, the Robin Hood Foundation,
Shareable, the United States Federation of Worker Cooperatives,
Ver.di, The Working World, and the Yale Information Society
Project.
With far more attendees than originally planned for, we also relied
on the work of intrepid volunteers, including Lauren Mobertz, Meg
Miner, Angela Difede, and countless others.
Throughout this process we have relied on the collaboration,
guidance, and support of our familiesClaire and Daniel Francis, and
Jenny, Rosa Clara, and Emma Luisa. They kindle our hope in a more
cooperative world and, for us, prove that it is possible.
251
FURTHER RESOURCES
LAUNCH EVENT
“Platform Cooperativism: The Internet, Ownership, Democracy,” The
New School (November 2015), video archive: http://platformcoo
p.net/2015/video
READINGS
Trebor Scholz, “Platform Cooperativism vs. the Sharing Economy,
Medium (December 5, 2014), https://tinyurl.com/oj8rna2
Nathan Schneider, “Owning Is the New Sharing, Shareable (December
21, 2014), http://shareable.net/blog/owning-is-the-new-sharing
Janelle Orsi, Frank Pasquale, Nathan Schneider, Pia Mancini, Trebor
Scholz, “5 Ways to Take Back Tech, The Nation (May 27, 2015),
http://thenation.com/article/5-ways-take-back-tech
Trebor Scholz, Platform Cooperativism: Challenging the Corporate Sharing
Economy (Rosa Luxemburg Stiftung, New York Oce, 2016, with
additional translations in Spanish, French, Portuguese, German,
Italian, and Chinese), http://platformcoop.net/about/primer
Trebor Scholz, Uberworked and Underpaid: How Workers are Disrupting
the Digital Economy (Polity, 2016)
WEBSITES
Platform Cooperativism portal, http://platformcoop.net
Platform Cooperativism Consortium, http://platformcoop.newschool.edu
The Internet of Ownership, http://internetofownership.net
Shareable, http://shareable.net
Sustainable Economies Law Center, http://theselc.org
OR Books
PUBLISHING THE POLITICS OF THE INTERNET
For more information, visit our
website at www.orbooks.com
What’s Yours is Mine: Against the Sharing Economy
T S
Black Ops Advertising: Native Ads, Content Marketing, and the Covert
World of the Digital Sell
M E
Splinternet: How Geopolitics and Commerce are Fragmenting the
World Wide Web
S M
Lean Out: The Struggle for Gender Equality in Tech and Start-Up Culture
E S, 
When Google Met WikiLeaks
J A
The Big Disconnect: Why the Internet Hasn’t Transformed Politics (Yet)
M L. S
Cypherpunks: Freedom and the Future of the Internet
J A  J A, A M-M,
 J Z
Hacking Politics: How Geeks, Progressives, the Tea Party, Gamers,
Anarchists and Suits Teamed Up to Defeat SOPA and Save the Internet
D M, P R,  D S, 